The onset of the Cold War transformed the conduct of international relations by establishing a new context. For U.S. policy makers the breakdown in relations with the Soviet Union after the Second World War became the central preoccupation. Seeking to build liberal-capitalist systems in as much of the world as possible, U.S. leaders guarded against presumed threats of Soviet expansion by applying the containment principles first in Western Europe and then in other regions. The consequences shaped U.S. dealings with most other countries. Those nations operating outside of the Soviet sphere became significant or not, depending on larger calculations of gain or loss in the Cold War struggle.
In the Western Hemisphere, U.S. leaders initially took much for granted. While working toward the construction of a regional collective security system, they embraced Latin American governments as political and military allies but otherwise looked upon the region as peripheral in importance. For that reason, they placed no equivalent emphasis on programs of economic modernization and development. Latin Americans, meanwhile, resented the neglect, regarding it as a sign of indifference and condescension. Yet for many of them, economic dependence on the United States had gone so far that breaking loose posed complicated problems.
Under Presidents Truman and Eisenhower the Good Neighbor policy lost viability as a guide. Neither president possessed much understanding of Latin America, and personnel changes in the State Department compounded the difficulty. In August 1943, Sumner Welles resigned as undersecretary after allegations of personal misbehavior. In November 1944, Cordell Hull, his health failing, also went into retirement. His successor was Edward R. Stettinius, Jr., a corporate executive who possessed no diplomatic experiences and no special appreciation for Latin American issues. According to Irwin Gellman, those shifts marked “the beginning of the disintegration in Pan American solidarity” by removing from authority the policy makers most committed to it.1
Questions of regional organization in the Western Hemisphere ranked high as priorities at the end of the Second World War. Drawing on wartime experiences stressing hemispheric solidarity, government leaders fashioned a regional system of collective security at a series of international conferences in Mexico City, San Francisco, Rio de Janeiro, and Bogotá. The system consisted of two parts, the Rio Pact, a military alliance, and the Organization of American States (OAS), a political counterpart. Taken together, these devices perpetuated at least an appearance of cooperation but otherwise elicited divergent appraisals. For enthusiasts, the creation of a regional system was laudable for reasons of national security. For critics, the system emanated from U.S. hegemonic aspirations and functioned essentially as an alliance between the United States and the established elites of Latin America in defense of the status quo.2
Serious discussions of regional organization for the postwar period got under way late in the war, prompted mainly by Argentine ambiguities. By remaining neutral, the Argentine government upheld what its leaders regarded as sovereign prerogatives and drove secretary of state Cordell Hull to distraction. He attributed the Argentine position to pro-Axis preferences. He also feared the destabilization of neighboring countries by pro-Nazi influences and wanted a cohesive alignment in support of the Allies. Actually an amalgam of various tendencies, the Argentine policy of neutrality followed from traditional aversions. Argentine nationalists perceived Pan American formulations as instruments of U.S. domination. Moreover, in a sense pro-Axis, neutrality showed the impact of German and Italian immigration; indeed, many Argentines conceived of their country as European. Another consideration was economic. For the most part, the Argentines lacked restrictive dependence on U.S. markets and capital and so possessed some additional room to maneuver. As producers of primary agricultural commodities such as beef, wheat, and mutton, they sold mainly in the British market. The British, for their part, had less concern about Argentine neutrality than about maintaining a reliable food supply.
The Argentine army took over the government in a bloodless coup in June 1943 by installing general Pedro Ramírez as interim president. The leaders, mainly high-ranking officers working through a secret society, the so-called Grupo de Oficiales Unidos, embraced some fascist notions about corporate unity and racial purity and also drew on traditional militarist beliefs in nationalism, hierarchy, and authority. For Argentine military officers the Franco and Mussolini regimes in Spain and Italy served as special inspirations. Nevertheless, the Ramírez government did promise to break with the Axis eventually. In fact, the new foreign minister, admiral Segundo Storni, naïvely asked for patience from the United States in a letter to secretary of state Cordell Hull in which he also urged large-scale military assistance for Argentina through Lend-Lease. To Hull, this request looked like a bribe. In full fury, he excoriated the Argentine government as a pro-fascist presence in South America. Storni had to resign. Replacing him as foreign minister, general Alberto Gilbert engaged in something of a balancing act, seeking to avoid giving offense to either the United States or other high-ranking Argentine officers. Some of them, notably colonel Juan Domingo Perón, an emerging power, opposed any concession to the United States as an insult to Argentine honor. When as a consequence of complicated political maneuvers General Ramírez withdrew from the presidency early in 1944, Hull withheld diplomatic recognition from the new government, headed by general Edelmiro Farrell. The secretary sought in this way to force a change in favor of the Allies; he also employed economic sanctions to escalate the pressure.3 The effort failed. Later, Hull himself resigned. Ill and exhausted, he retired from the State Department soon after Roosevelt won the presidential election in November 1944.
Meanwhile, cross-purposes in the State Department contributed to other diplomatic confusions. Hull’s successor, secretary of state Edward Stettinius, functioned mainly as a figurehead. For a time, he upheld Hull’s policy of nonrecognition toward Argentina and thus incurred a challenge from Nelson Rockefeller. Young, smart, rich, and ambitious, Rockefeller became the undersecretary of state for Latin American affairs following Sumner Welles’s departure. Unlike Hull and Stettinius, Rockefeller regarded nonrecognition as ineffective and counterproductive. He favored a more conciliatory position toward Argentina, a preference shared by most Latin American diplomats. As a means of clarifying its status the Argentine government requested a special inter-American conference. Disinclined to risk public embarrassment, Stettinius wanted no such gathering but hesitated to oppose it outright. To resolve the dilemma, Mexican foreign minister Ezequiel Padilla then proposed a conference of foreign ministers in Mexico City. This approach allowed for international discussions of the Argentine problem without direct Argentine participation: Under the rules, only those countries that had broken relations with the Axis powers or declared war upon them would receive invitations.4
The Mexico City conference met at Chapultepec Palace from February 21 until March 8, 1945. Headed by Secretary Stettinius, the U.S. delegation wanted a carefully controlled agenda to avoid controversy over Argentina and to maintain the appearance of hemispheric solidarity. Other potentially troublesome and divisive issues included the relationship between the nations of the Western Hemisphere and the proposed United Nations organization, one of Franklin Roosevelt’s favorite projects. At the Dumbarton Oaks conference in Washington late in the summer of 1944, the Big Three—the United States, Great Britain, and the Soviet Union—had accepted commitments to create a new world organization, conceiving of it as something like a remodeled League of Nations. The idea was popular in the United States, especially among Democrats, who looked upon it as a “second chance”: that is, an opportunity to atone for the rejection of the Treaty of Versailles after the First World War. Administration planners wanted the United States to participate in a postwar system of collective security based solidly on the expectation of continued cooperation among the Big Three. Yet unanswered questions produced high levels of uncertainty. What of the impact on existing regional arrangements, such as the Western Hemisphere system? Would this new organization take precedence over them? Could the United Nations sanction interference from the outside in Western Hemisphere affairs, possibly even military intervention?
Among officials in the State Department the discussions ranged around two broad choices. Advocates of the first portrayed the prerogatives of the United Nations as superior to those of regional systems. These “universalists” included Alger Hiss and Leo Pasvolsky, both attached to the State Department’s International Organization Division. They worried about the emergence of regional spheres of influence and regarded any such outcome as incompatible with a truly international system. To check such tendencies, they wanted to vest the dominant decision-making authority in the United Nations. Critics saw this approach as expanding the role of the Great Powers too much at the expense of the smaller states. Consequently, a group of “regionalists” in the State Department advocated a second option. Led by Nelson Rockefeller, they called for a self-sustaining, collective-security system in the Western Hemisphere as protection against outside meddling and the possibility of subjugation to the Great Powers. One of the regionalists, Adolf A. Berle, the U.S. ambassador to Brazil, conjured up dire possibilities. Adoption of the universalist option “would mean that the United States and others could not prevent Argentina from seizing Uruguay without the consent of Britain and Russia—who at the moment might be backing Argentina.” In short, the universalist alternative “would introduce European diplomacy into every inter-American dispute.”5
Latin Americans desired a regional system for their own reasons. They wanted protection against external interference and also against the United States. At the same time, they perceived in such arrangements a means of facilitating the infusion of U.S. economic aid into Latin America. During the war, at the third meeting of foreign ministers in Rio de Janeiro in January 1942, Sumner Welles had encouraged this expectation by promising U.S. support for Latin American economic development. He hoped to raise living standards by means of aid and assistance for industrialization, modernization, and diversification. To Latin Americans, such rewards seemed proper responses, given their magnitude of support for the Allies during the war.6
The outcome of the Mexico City conference, the Act of Chapultepec, allowed for multiple approaches toward common goals. The measure endorsed Latin American preferences by recommending in favor of a “regional arrangement” to maintain peace and security in the Western Hemisphere. It also affirmed support for “the purposes and principles” of the United Nations.7 By combining the one with the other, the delegates maintained their options, seeking to accommodate both the universalist and the regionalist position.
For Latin Americans, economic relations in the postwar period took on special significance. During the war, they had benefited from special arrangements assuring extensive sales in foreign markets at good prices. Now they worried about the impact of falling prices and shrinking sales in contracting markets. As safeguards, some favored protective tariffs to nurture infant industries; others advocated commodity agreements to stabilize prices. Most hoped for U.S. aid, specifically in the form of loans and grants to bolster growth and diversification. As Mexican foreign minister Ezequiel Padilla pointed out at Chapultepec, it was “vital for the [Latin] Americans to do more than produce raw materials and live in a state of semi-colonialism.” He looked for some form of assistance from the United States.8
Instead of assurances, he got statements of high capitalist principle. The speeches by U.S. delegates indicated that prewar suspicion of economic nationalism and state enterprise in Latin America had not gone away. Indeed, according to official U.S. views, restrictive trade and investment practices in the 1930s had contributed to the world crisis by encouraging cutthroat international competition and eventually war. To avoid “shortsighted” policies, undersecretary of state Dean Acheson affirmed his belief in free trade as the best means of expanding commerce, enhancing prosperity, reducing world tension, and promoting peace. These views were established orthodoxy among U.S. leaders. As assessed by the historian R. A. Humphreys, the implications for Latin America meant some measure of U.S. encouragement for economic development but typically “within the context of an expanding, interdependent and liberalized world economy.” Overall, the discussion placed the United States in opposition to Latin American efforts to escape from “economic vassalage to the more industrialized countries.”
Finally, the delegates at Chapultepec addressed the question of Argentine neutrality by affirming a resolution of censure. It castigated Argentine leaders for possessing pro-fascist sympathies and maintaining Axis ties. It also proposed the means of rectification. To set things right, Argentina would have to adhere immediately to Allied principles and issue a war declaration. This outcome gratified Secretary of State Stettinius, an heir of Hull’s anti-Argentine animosity. He extolled the achievements of the Chapultepec conference, however vague and mixed, as splendid things and hyperbolically characterized the experience as “a culmination of the Good Neighbor Policy.” Whatever the fissures and cleavages among them, the Western Hemisphere nations had retained an appearance of hemispheric solidarity.
The United Nations conference got under way in San Francisco on April 25, 1945. Forty-six countries sent delegations, including nineteen from Latin America—but not Argentina. The neutrality question still caused friction. The Farrell government in Argentina received no invitation, even though the leaders had complied with the Act of Chapultepec by declaring war upon Germany and Japan on March 27, 1945. The problem now resided in Great-Power politics. The Soviet Union regarded Argentina as a pro-fascist enemy state, undeserving of participation in the San Francisco conference. Somewhat more forgiving, the other Latin American delegations accepted in better faith the Argentine war declaration, however belated. With the support of the United States, they suggested a workable solution. If the Soviets wanted “White Russia” and the Ukraine to have representation at the conference, they could do so, but only if Argentina could take part.9
At San Francisco, Latin Americans displayed special interest in the structure of decision-making authority but otherwise exercised scant influence. To head off Great-Power domination, they hoped for a broad allocation of responsibility to the smaller states in the General Assembly and also for a permanent Latin American seat on the Security Council; President Vargas of Brazil thought his country a candidate for such a spot. In these matters, Latin Americans achieved none of their goals. The Security Council fell under the control of the Big Three, each with veto power, and the General Assembly functioned primarily as an international debating society. These outcomes reflected political realities. The United States, Great Britain, and the Soviet Union, having invested the greatest effort in winning the victory over the Axis powers, also wielded the greatest influence when the conflict ended.
Other discussions centered on ways to reconcile regional and universal approaches. For Latin Americans, the Act of Chapultepec remained the guide. They wanted to reconcile the purposes and principles of the inter-American system with those of the world organization, seeking among other things safeguards against outsiders, including the United States. Meanwhile, the U.S. delegation divided into factions. Secretary Stettinius espoused the universalist option while affirming Great-Power prerogatives. In his view, “we must not be pushed around by a lot of small American republics who are dependent on us in many ways—economically, politically, militarily.” But different arguments based on other considerations undercut Stettinius’s position and prepared the way for a kind of blending process.
The defense of the Monroe Doctrine especially concerned conservative nationalists. They regarded this ancient creed as the embodiment of U.S. tradition and experience and would sanction neither concessions nor compromises which, they warned, would bring dire consequences. What of the prerogative to guard against European intrusions? What of the political implications? Could a failure to uphold the Monroe Doctrine result in rejection of the United Nations in the U.S. Senate? Or conversely, could acceptance of the United Nations mean repudiation of the Monroe Doctrine? These touchy matters required clarification and of course recalled the debate in 1919 over the Versailles treaty. Senator Arthur P. Vandenberg, a Republican from Michigan and a U.S. delegate at San Francisco, had described the Monroe Doctrine in 1926 as “the indispensable bulwark of American independence.” As Gaddis Smith explains, his views in 1945 had not changed: “No politician . . . was more steeped emotionally and intellectually in the principles of the Monroe Doctrine.”
Under the terms of article 51, the UN Charter, as written at San Francisco, provided the means of reconciling universalist and regionalist views by allowing for a form of coexistence: It sanctioned the exercise of regional prerogatives within the context of the world organization. More specifically, it recognized for each member “the inherent right of individual and collective self-defense,” thereby permitting defensive measures to be taken alone or in cooperation with others, pending action by the Security Council. Humphreys calls article 51 “the great compromise.” Less positively, he also claims that it established “the legal basis of the post-war blocs that marked the Cold War.” This long-term implication, not so clear at the time, caused no bother for Senator Vandenberg. In a celebratory mood, he affirmed, “We have preserved the Monroe Doctrine and the Inter-American system . . . We have retained a complete veto—exclusive in our own hands—over any decisions involving external activities.”10
Meanwhile, the disintegration of the wartime alliance between the United States and the Soviet Union initiated a Cold War, resulting in mounting levels of acrimony, mistrust, and confrontation. During the early stages, as Walter LaFeber has explained, the rivalry centered on the shape and structure of the postwar world, symbolized for him by the terms “Open Doors” and “Iron Curtains.” For U.S. leaders the essential parts of Woodrow Wilson’s liberal-capitalist internationalism retained fundamental validity. They wanted an open world based on free trade, liberal democracy, and collective security. For Soviet leaders, however, the Open Door approach had no appeal. To restore their war-ravaged country, they preferred an emphasis on spheres of influence, notably an extension of the Soviet system into the countries of Eastern Europe. An immense historiographical controversy surrounds the causes of the Cold War. In accounting for Soviet behavior and the split with the United States, modern scholars debate among themselves the relative importance of economic and security considerations, Joseph Stalin’s distinctive personality, and the impact of Marxist ideology. For a combination of reasons, Stalin chose to seclude the Soviet domains after the war through the creation of a “closed system” sealed off, in Churchill’s phrase, by an Iron Curtain.11
In response to mounting difficulties around the world, the Truman administration took alarm over the possibility of Soviet expansion into other regions and endorsed the necessity of containing the communist threat. At the same time, U.S. leaders pursued their own spheres-of-influence policies in the New World. Unbothered by the inconsistency, they denied any sort of parallel. Only secretary of commerce Henry A. Wallace perceived an incongruity, noting that the Russians “might feel about the Balkan states in somewhat the same way as we feel about Latin America.” In a famous speech in March 1946 at Madison Square Garden in New York City, he stated his conviction that “we should recognize that we have no more business in the political affairs of eastern Europe than Russia has in the political affairs of Latin America.” For enunciating such heresy, Truman fired him soon thereafter.12
Caught up in a contradiction, the leaders in the Truman administration wanted the Open Door in other regions but regarded Latin America as closed because of special ties with the United States. But then in the famous speech setting forth the Truman Doctrine before the Congress on March 12, 1947, the president found a way of bridging the gap. This speech, the first component in what became the containment policy against Soviet communism, called for extraordinary measures in response to a civil war in Greece. Truman wanted an allocation of $400 million from the Congress to sustain programs of economic and military aid and assistance in the eastern Mediterranean region. In justification, he stressed “the gravity of the situation.” In his view, the ideological struggle between democrats and communists in Greece also had geopolitical implications. A communist victory in Greece could threaten Turkey and the rest of the Middle East with Soviet subversion and aggression. To ward off this dread possibility, Truman argued, “it must be the policy of the United States to support free peoples who are resisting attempted subjugation by armed minorities and outside pressures.” For good measure, he insisted, “We must assist free peoples to work out their own destinies in their own way.”13
Through this formulation, as Gaddis Smith explains, “Truman resolved the problem” with Latin America. By extending “to the entire world the definition of American interest in protecting small nations from external coercion,” the Truman Doctrine in effect transformed the Monroe Doctrine into a global policy. A contemporary journalist, James Reston of the New York Times, drew the same inference. He described Truman’s address as the most important statement in U.S. foreign policy since 1823. In Reston’s words, “Like the Monroe Doctrine,” the Truman Doctrine “warned that the United States would resist efforts to impose a political system or foreign domination on areas vital to our security.” For this reason, the Soviets had better keep hands off or risk the consequences.14
Meanwhile, Latin American diplomats initiated a process for creating an inter-American collective security system through the implementation of article 51 of the UN Charter. In August 1945, Brazil offered to host a meeting of American republics in Rio de Janeiro to devise a treaty. At first the United States resisted, again because of Argentina. The Truman administration was reluctant to sign a treaty with president Juan Domingo Perón’s government. Indeed, U.S. leaders regarded Perón as an unreconstructed pro-fascist and mounted a determined campaign against him.
The anti-Perón movement, eventually a kind of fiasco, followed from wartime suspicions and Spruille Braden’s obsessions. A professional diplomat with experience in Latin America, Braden went to Buenos Aires as U.S. ambassador in May 1945 and developed an intense dislike for Perón, then the vice president, because of his pro-fascist reputation and a reportedly anti-U.S. attitude that Braden characterized as “neurotic nationalism.”15 When Braden later adopted the practice of criticizing Perón in public, presumably seeking to bring him down, he went too far. Perón turned the tables, depicting Braden as persona non grata because of his undiplomatic partisanship.
To avoid trouble, the Truman administration recalled Braden to Washington in September 1945, assigning to him responsibilities as assistant secretary of state for American republic affairs. Now, unwisely and ineffectively, he pursued a long distance vendetta. For example, he allowed himself to become identified with a loosely conceived proposal floating about to destroy Perón by means of a joint international intervention. Braden also meddled in Argentine politics. Perón had become the front-running candidate in the presidential campaign. Seeking to block him, Braden instigated the publication of a State Department Blue Book in February 1946, a short while before the election; it consisted of a compilation of documents, reiterating the charge that Argentina had pursued pro-fascist policies during the war. Without much plausibility, U.S. officials denied any political intent. Unpersuaded, the historian Roger Trask explains that “the Blue Book was an effort to influence Argentine votes against Perón,” and it failed. Indeed, it enabled Perón to mobilize Argentine nationalism against the United States by brandishing the slogan “Perón or Braden.” Given the choice, Argentines voted for Perón. An embarrassing failure on all counts, Braden’s obsession with Perón not only demonstrated an incapacity to influence Argentine elections but also aroused concern among Latin Americans elsewhere over resurgent threats of U.S. intervention. The debacle further diminished the legacies of the Good Neighbor policy.
Braden’s successor in Argentina, George S. Messersmith, formerly the ambassador to Mexico, favored a more conciliatory approach. This preference ran parallel with those of his superiors in the State Department who wanted to place relations with Argentina on a more regular basis. They also wanted to move ahead with the negotiation of an inter-American defense treaty. From his post in Buenos Aires, Messersmith defended his position by writing long letters to President Truman, secretary of state James F. Byrnes, and undersecretary of state Dean Acheson in which he attacked Spruille Braden for an assortment of misdeeds and misconceptions. At the same time, Messersmith developed an argument based on Cold War assumptions and perceptions for supporting Perón as a strong anticommunist. Seeking support on exactly those grounds, Perón subsequently switched tactics to cultivate leaders in the Truman administration. Now a proponent of diplomatic accommodation, he claimed to foresee an impending war with the Soviet Union, in which case, he vowed, Argentina would side with the United States.
From the Argentine viewpoint, these policy adjustments had good effects by edging the two countries toward the establishment of more normal relations. They also opened the way for the negotiation of an inter-American collective defense treaty at a conference in Rio de Janeiro, beginning on August 15, 1947. Headed by general George C. Marshall, the new secretary of state, the U.S. delegation included senator Arthur P. Vandenberg, the new chairman of the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, who occupied the position as a consequence of Republican victory in the off-year elections of 1946; for the first time since 1928, they controlled the Congress. Also in attendance, Truman arrived ceremoniously aboard the USS Missouri, the great battleship on whose decks the Japanese had surrendered in Tokyo Bay two years earlier.16
Formally known as the Inter-American Conference for the Maintenance of Continental Peace and Security, this assembly resulted in the negotiation of a mutual defense treaty among nations within the region. In the Inter-American Treaty of Reciprocal Assistance, also called the Rio Pact, the participants accepted three vital provisions. In the first, they promised to seek peaceful settlements in disputes among themselves before appealing to the United Nations. In the second, they embraced the essential feature of collective security by vowing to look upon an attack against any one of them as an attack against all of them. In the third, they agreed that any resort to collective action would depend upon a two-thirds majority vote and that no state ever would have to use force against its will. Senator Vandenberg, a leading player, waxed eloquent in his request for Senate ratification: “We have sealed a New World pact of peace which possesses teeth. We have translated Pan-American solidarity from an ideal into a reality . . . This is sunlight in a dark world.” The Senate then passed favorably on the treaty by a vote of 72to 1. As Gaddis Smith notes, “For Vandenberg the Monroe Doctrine had never been so alive and well.”17
Among Latin Americans, too, the pact aroused enthusiasm although, as Roger Trask observes, “the motives of the various American republics varied to a considerable extent.” Some took the affirmations of anticommunist purpose seriously. The Argentines, for example, expressed their desire for “a completely united front against extra-hemisphere aggressions, particularly against Russia.” For others, economic needs assumed importance. As Trask notes, “One gets the impression that the mutual defense treaty was a secondary concern, perhaps looked upon as something to trade to the United States in return for economic assistance.” Mexican foreign minister Jaime Torres Bodet candidly remarked that economic development was “the one way to provide [the] only sound basis for hemisphere peace.” Brazilian foreign minister Raúl Fernandes urged that the United States instigate a large-scale program of aid and assistance to bring about economic change in the Western Hemisphere. To the extent that such words represented Latin American expectations, Truman effectively squelched them in his address before the assembled delegates. While claiming that he understood “the economic problems common to the nations of North and South America,” he stated, “We have been obliged . . . to differentiate between the urgent need for rehabilitation of war-shattered areas and the problems of development elsewhere.” To underscore the point, he said, “The problems of countries in this Hemisphere are different in nature and cannot be relieved by the same means and the same approaches which are in contemplation for Europe.” Although acknowledging a need “for long-term economic collaboration,” Truman assigned “a much greater role . . . to private citizens and groups than is the case in a program designed to aid European countries to recover from the destruction of war.”18 In other words, he envisioned no equivalent of the Marshall Plan for Latin America.
First proposed by the secretary of state in a commencement address at Harvard University in June 1947, the Marshall Plan was the second component in the containment policy, after the Truman Doctrine. It called for the use of large-scale aid and assistance, ultimately $12.4 billion, to promote the economic reconstruction of Western Europe. For the citizens of the United States, it became a subject of “almost limitless self-congratulation . . . then and since.” For Latin Americans, it became a cause of resentment and ill will, a “sorry proof of American priorities.” When asked at a press conference about a Marshall Plan for Latin America, Truman replied: “Well, I think there has always been a Marshall Plan in effect for the Western Hemisphere. The foreign policy of the United States in that direction has been set for one hundred years, known as the Monroe Doctrine.” As Gaddis Smith observes, “It is difficult to say whether that comment demonstrated more confusion about the Marshall Plan or about the Monroe Doctrine.”19
Meanwhile, the concluding step in bringing about an inter-American collective security system took place at the Ninth International Conference of American States in Bogotá, Colombia. This gathering lasted from March 30 to May 2, 1948, resulting in the transformation of the old Pan American Union into the Organization of American States. Again led by Secretary Marshall, the U.S. delegation embraced a plan to sidestep the issue of economic assistance by mobilizing resistance against what they perceived as an escalating communist menace. During the preliminaries, U.S. planning documents placed great importance on the development of anticommunist measures for implementation within the inter-American system. They described communism in the Western Hemisphere in alarming terms, characterizing it as a “potential danger,” a “tool of the Kremlin,” “a direct and major threat to the national security of the United States, and to that of all the other American Republics.” Marshall himself underscored the issue by warning of “foreign-inspired subversive activities directed against [the] institutions and peace and security of American Republics.”20
With apprehension running high, U.S. diplomats anticipated trouble at Bogotá. The ambassador, Willard S. Beaulac, cautioned against possible disruptions by “Communists and left wing Liberals.” As if in fulfillment of his forecast, on April 9 an assassin killed Jorge Eliécer Gaitán, a Colombian politician and reformer in the Liberal Party. Subsequently, a mob lynched the suspected murderer, Juan Roa Sierra, and put the corpse on display in front of the presidential palace. The ensuing violence, known in Colombian history as the Bogotazo, featured several days of killing, rioting, and looting in the course of which the conference site, the Capitolio, came under attack. State Department officials urged General Marshall to come home at once, but he refused. In his view, fleeing would encourage revolutionary movements elsewhere. Marshall attributed the outbreak to communist provocations. Historians with the advantage of hindsight are less categorical. According to Roger Trask, “The riots were essentially an emotional response to the death of a charismatic leader and communist participation was incidental”; Stephen J. Randall points out that CIA observers at the time attributed Gaitán’s assassination to an act of personal vengeance. Whatever the cause, the rioting had important consequences. For one thing, it intensified the conflict between Liberals and Conservatives in Colombia and brought about “the virtual collapse” of the political system. For another, it encouraged Latin American support at the conference for an anticommunist resolution favored by the United States. Formally titled “The Preservation and Defense of Democracy in America,” the resolution affirmed “that by its antidemocratic nature and its interventionist tendency, the political activity of international communism or any totalitarian doctrine is incompatible with the concept of American freedom.” As a safeguard, each nation should adopt “measures necessary to eradicate and prevent activities directed, assisted, or instigated by foreign governments, organizations, or individuals.”21
Most significantly, the Bogotá conference brought into existence the Organization of American States, which, according to Trask, “provided an institutional framework for the inter-American system and machinery for implementation of the Rio pact.”22 The OAS charter endorsed as goals the pursuit of “peace and justice”; the advancement of “collaboration” and “solidarity” among the states; and the defense of national “sovereignty,” “territorial integrity,” and “independence.” As a fundamental principle, the document affirmed equality among the states; decision making would depend on simple majority rule, whether carried out during inter-American conferences or during meetings of foreign ministers. Unlike the UN Security Council, the OAS gave no government a veto power. Finally, article 15 formally embraced an absolute version of the principle of nonintervention: “No State or group of States has the right to intervene, directly or indirectly, for any reason whatever, in the internal or external affairs of any other State.” It also excluded the use of armed force and “any other form of interference or attempted threat” against the state and “its political, economic and cultural elements.”23 Whether such terms actually could constrain the United States remained an issue for decision in the future.
The legacies of Franklin Roosevelt’s Good Neighbor policy faded away during the early Cold War, providing ever less guidance for diplomatic conduct in the Western Hemisphere. Under Presidents Truman and Eisenhower, anticommunism dominated official thinking. The consequences encouraged order and stability as the primary goals and afforded conservative elites in Latin American with incentives to counteract recent political losses. According to the historians Leslie Bethell and Ian Roxborough, the “conjuncture” at the end of the Second World War had important ramifications, among them, a halt in the growth of democratization and a restoration of more traditional forms of authoritarian rule.24
This thesis appears more fully in Bethell and Roxborough’s Latin America between the Second World War and the Cold War. Presented as a series of case studies on a country-by-country basis, the essays argue that from 1944 to 1948 each Latin American republic fashioned “its own history” yet displayed “striking similarities.” As the editors explain, late in the war and immediately after, “three distinct but interrelated phenomena” threatened to undermine the political status quo. These consisted of, first, more extensive popular participation in government, second, a shift to the political left and, third, a growing militancy within the labor movement. Seeking to thwart such challenges, conservative elites marshaled resistance, blunted the effects, and reasserted their traditional prerogatives.25
Popular parties with mass followings toward the end of the Second World War expanded democratic bases by insisting upon free elections. In some countries the existence of rudimentary democratic forms already existed. In others, authoritarian traditions presented formidable obstacles. In most of Latin America, “reformist” and “progressive” parties became identified with urban interests, including middle- and working-class elements. At the same time, radical groups, often Marxist in orientation, scored political gains, usually in conjunction with the mobilization of labor unions. In some countries, “the incorporation of organized labor into democratic politics” took place for the first time.
Soon after the war the traditional, conservative elites in Latin America struck back, often by repressive means. They targeted for special attention political activists, agitators, union organizers, radicals, communists, and others they looked upon as dangerous. The outcome, a “historic defeat” for the popular parties, marked a lost opportunity “for significant political and social change.” Two developments account for the setback: “The shifting balance of domestic political forces in each country” and “the complex interaction between domestic and international politics as the Second World War came to an end.” In the latter case, the U.S. role in Latin America took on special importance.
Convincing evidence of increased democratization exists for the mid-1940s. At the beginning of 1944, only Uruguay, Chile, Costa Rica, and Colombia could claim with much veracity to possess functioning democracies: that is, elected civilian governments operating under the rule of law, while respecting civil liberties such as freedom of speech, association, and assembly. Mexico, a special case, conducted regular elections under the tight control of the ruling party, the Partido Revolucionario Mexicano (PRM). Elsewhere, authoritarian governments prevailed. They were “narrowly oligarchical and often repressive regimes,” typically “military or military-backed dictatorships, some benevolent, some brutal, and most personalistic.”
Democratization took place in Ecuador, Cuba, Panama, Peru, Venezuela, and Mexico, when popular pressure from the people compelled freer electoral procedures and forced transitions away from military or military-backed dictatorships. In Guatemala in July 1944, for example, a popular, urban-based uprising brought down the dictator Jorge Ubico. In Brazil early in 1945, Getúlio Vargas in effect dismantled the Estado Nôvo by making plans for presidential and congressional elections. In the same year, massive street demonstrations in Buenos Aires set in motion a sequence of events leading to democratic Argentine elections in February 1946. And in Bolivia during the summer of 1946 a liberal-left coalition overturned a military government. In the estimation of one contemporary observer, historian Arthur P. Whitaker, these occurrences taken together signified “more democratic changes in more Latin American countries” than at any time since the wars of independence. Notable exceptions, of course, existed in Paraguay, El Salvador, Honduras, Nicaragua, and the Dominican Republic, but even those dictatorial governments had to make “token gestures toward political liberalization.”
The Allied victory over the fascist powers functioned as “the principal factor” underlying these changes. To be sure, urban-based, democratic groups, from both the middle and working classes, drew on “a strong liberal tradition” in Latin America while demanding a more open form of politics. At the same time, the triumphant democracies of the United States and Great Britain compelled the “dominant groups in Latin America, including the military . . . to make some political and ideological adjustments and concessions.” During the war “an extraordinary outpouring of wartime propaganda” favored “U.S. political institutions, the U.S. economic model, and the American way of (and standard of) life.” Democracy emerged as “a central symbol with almost universal resonance,” in part because of the role played by the United States.
The democratization process also featured the inclusion of “progressive” parties of the center and the left. Important examples were the Acción Democrática in Venezuela, the Alianza Popular Revolucionaria Americana in Peru, and the Partido Revolucionario Cubano-Auténtico in Cuba. Highly personalist and populist in orientation, these parties secured support from the urban middle classes, the working classes, and in some instances the rural poor. Among other things, they offered “an extension of democracy, social reform, and national economic development.” Marxists too, especially communists, made gains, in part because of the Soviet Union’s role in the Allied coalition. After years of “weakness, isolation, and for the most part illegality . . . the Latin American Communist parties achieved for a brief period a degree of popularity, power, and influence—which would never be recaptured, except in Cuba after 1959 and (briefly) in Chile in the early seventies.”
Communist parties became legal in most Latin American countries during the war years. The total membership, less than 100,000 in 1939, increased to about 500,000 in 1947. The parties claimed 180,000 members in Brazil, 30,000 in Argentina, 50,000 in Chile, 35,000 in Peru, 20,000 in Venezuela, 55,000 in Cuba, 11,000 in Mexico, 10,000 in Colombia, and 15,000 in Uruguay. Though probably exaggerated, these figures indicate “an important presence of Communist parties in the major countries.” For a time, they enjoyed a measure of electoral success, especially in coalitions with other parties of the center and the left. The explanation resides “primarily in the war itself and its outcome.” Following the German invasion of the Soviet Union in June 1941, Latin American communists advocated a political truce with the pro-Allied governments in power, no matter how authoritarian or reactionary. They also played down conceptions of class conflict and encouraged notions of national unity. At the same time, Latin American governments relaxed their earlier strictures against communists. In the short run, communist parties ranked among “the beneficiaries” of victory and democratization.
Organized labor also benefited, especially in Mexico, Argentina, and Brazil. Mainly because of industrialization, import-substitution strategies, rapid population growth, and mass migrations from rural into urban areas, the working classes grew in numbers, especially in the service and transportation sectors, in mining and light manufacturing, and in textiles and food processing. “For the first time. something approaching a recognizably modern proletariat was coming into existence.” Similarly, expanded union membership by 1946 reached 3.5 to 4 million workers. The Confederación de Trabajadores de América Latina (Confederation of Latin American Workers), founded in 1938 and headed by a Mexican Marxist, Vicente Lombardo Toledano, reportedly represented some 3.3 million members in sixteen countries. Moreover, since union membership clustered in key industrial and transportation sectors, labor militancy, strikes, and agitation could exercise the greatest clout in vulnerable areas. Although, as Bethell and Roxborough remark, “democrats, leftists, and labor militants were not always and everywhere on the same side,” their efforts—“for the most part linked and mutually reinforcing”—nevertheless, constituted “a serious challenge to the established order, at least in the perceptions of the governments of the time.” That challenge, whether real or perceived, also elicited countermeasures from traditional elites.
In the immediate postwar period, conservative shifts effectively curbed democratizing tendencies almost everywhere. More closely policed, labor unions fell under state control, often muzzled by antistrike legislation. Purges removed radical leaders from positions of influence, and communist affiliations again became illegal. Taken together, these actions represented “a marked tendency to restrict or curtail political competition and participation, to contain or repress popular mobilization, and to frustrate reformist aspirations.” Within a decade, as a consequence, outright dictatorships existed in eleven Latin American countries: Guatemala, El Salvador, Honduras, Nicaragua, Panama, Cuba, the Dominican Republic, Venezuela, Colombia, Peru, and Paraguay.
Bethell and Roxborough explain these reversals by underscoring “the continuing strength of the dominant classes.” Unlike those in other parts of the world, the traditional elites in Latin America, including the military, “had not been weakened, much less destroyed by the Second World War.” Instead, they had assumed a defensive posture, intending subsequently “to restore the political and social control that was threatened by the political mobilization of ‘the dangerous classes.’” The “most progressive parties” also displayed debilitating, internal weaknesses. Often they lacked such vital prerequisites for success as “deep roots” in society, internal cohesion, and “a vocation for power.” Overall, they possessed insufficient means to maintain their gains when traditional oligarchs reasserted their authority and privilege.
Bethell and Roxborough also emphasize the importance of “the international environment” at the beginning of the Cold War. According to them, “the international stance” of the United States “reinforced domestic attitudes and tendencies,” providing for “an ideological justification for the shift to the right” and for “the counteroffensive” against labor and the left. In many cases, in the official versions set forth by Latin American governments, “popular political mobilization and strike activity, whether or not Communist-led, suddenly became Communist-inspired, Moscow-dictated, and therefore ‘subversive.’” Such ploys catered to U.S. preferences and prejudices.
In addition, “the new international economic order and Latin America’s place in it” influenced elite perceptions. During the early Cold War the U.S. refusal of economic aid and assistance in favor of private capital conveyed important messages. To attract foreign investors, Latin American governments had to provide “an appropriate climate for direct investment.” This requirement meant “various guarantees and assurances, both symbolic and real,” including commitment to “liberal, capitalist development and to an ‘ideology of production.’” The necessary conditions allowed for no more “Mexican stunts,” to use financier Bernard Baruch’s term for the oil expropriation in 1938. For such reasons the elites moved against radicals, communists, and labor leaders. Bethell and Roxborough conclude, “Above all, political stability was essential if foreign capital were to be invested in Latin American industry.” The observation highlights the importance of external constraints. “Thus, just as the United States indirectly promoted political and social change in Latin America at the end of the Second World War, it indirectly imposed limits on change in the postwar years.”
During the early Cold War the Soviet Union posed no threat of outright aggression against Latin America or any other place in the Western Hemisphere; Soviet leaders possessed neither the means nor, for that matter, the intent—but U.S. leaders worried about communist subversion and penetration by political and ideological methods. Consequently, the intelligence operations initially set up to monitor Nazi activity shifted attention to the communists. In U.S. embassies the legal attachés (usually FBI agents), the military, naval, and labor attachés, and the CIA operatives who made up the apparatus found scant evidence of a threat. A CIA review of Soviet aims in Latin America in November 1947 denied any possibility of a communist takeover anywhere in the region. But such findings ran counter to official U.S. preferences. At the 1948 Bogotá conference the delegate described the mere existence of communist parties as a menace to regional security.
U.S. leaders worried especially about communism in Latin American labor unions. Presumably, such influence could endanger U.S. interests in vital enterprises, such as petroleum in Mexico and Venezuela, copper in Chile, sugar in Cuba, and industry and transportation everywhere. Moreover, militant unions, whether or not controlled by communists, appeared as destabilizing elements, fundamentally at odds with the requirements of postwar capitalist development. In most countries the United States had no need to intervene, even by clandestine means, to secure action against communists and labor militants. The ruling elites correctly understood U.S. preferences and responded to U.S. political and economic pressures. As the leaders in the Truman administration saw it, the removal of communists strengthened democracy by expunging alien and hostile presences.26
Overall, the Cold War diverted U.S. attention away from Latin America. The containment policy initially manifested a Europe-first orientation that culminated in 1949 with the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO), a formal military alliance and collective security system. It rounded out a sequence of impressive victories for the United States. But then, a turnabout ostensibly situated the advantage with the other side. In August 1949, only four years after Hiroshima and Nagasaki, the Soviet Union broke the U.S. atomic monopoly by setting off a nuclear device. In October 1949, another hammerblow fell: Communist forces under Mao Zedong triumphed in the Chinese civil war, and in the following year the People’s Republic of China negotiated a mutual defense pact and military alliance with the Soviet Union. Even worse, the onset of a war in Korea in June 1950 threatened to ignite a global conflict.
As viewed from Washington, these calamitous events indicated a shift in the distribution of world power favoring the Soviet Union, and U.S. responses incorporated frightening, perhaps distorted, assessments of Soviet aims and capabilities. One such appraisal by the National Security Council known as NSC-68 took shape early in 1950. A powerful endorsement of prevailing assumptions among U.S. officials, the text remained classified until 1975. Alarmist and hyperbolic in content, it presumed the existence of a grave crisis and a mortal threat. As the historian Walter LaFeber observes, it established “the American blueprint for waging the Cold War during the next twenty years.”27
NSC-68 began by describing a profound change in the world balance of power. As a consequence of the Second World War the two Great Powers, the United States and the Soviet Union, dominated the globe. The document then spelled out the implications: “What is new, what makes the continuing crisis, is the polarization of power which inescapably confronts the slave society with the free.” As LaFeber notes, “It was us against them.” NSC-68 attributed the threat of Soviet aggression largely to Marxist ideology. Much in vogue at the time, this analysis claimed that the Soviet Union was “animated by a new fanatic faith, antithetical to our own,” which sought “to impose its absolute authority over the rest of the world.” The ensuing struggle, “endemic” and “momentous,” entailed high stakes. The Soviets presumably would use “violent or nonviolent methods in accordance with the dictates of expediency.” By setting forth a “design” seeking total victory, their ambitions called into question “the fulfillment or destruction not only of this Republic but of civilization itself.” The Soviets wanted “the complete subversion or forcible destruction of the machinery of government and structure of society in the countries of the non-Soviet world and their replacement by an apparatus and structure subservient to and controlled from the Kremlin.” No compromise was possible.
Most historians in the present day probably would tone down these assessments of Soviet motives and goals. Nevertheless, for many contemporaries the prospect of terrible consequences seemed real enough. How could they avert them? Predictably, NSC-68 called upon the United States to take the lead “in building a successful functioning political and economic system in the free world” to deter “an attack upon us” so that “our free society can flourish.” It advised against premature negotiations with the Soviet Union, favoring instead the construction of positions of strength based on a buildup of U.S. military forces, both conventional and nuclear. It also affirmed a need for calculated measures to ensure “unity” and “consensus” at home and to maintain strong alliance systems with other anticommunist nations.28
Such expansive definitions of the communist menace encouraged U.S. leaders to think of Latin America almost exclusively in a Cold War context. The region ceased to have much significance in its own right; instead, it became an arena of Cold War competition in which the United States and the Soviet Union would play out a contest for power, resources, prestige, and influence. Typically, U.S. leaders looked upon Latin Americans as minor players who should subordinate their wishes, interests, and aspirations to Cold War imperatives as defined by the United States. Indeed, their countries took on importance not because of anything intrinsic to them but because of connections with the larger struggle. U.S. officials tended to regard Latin America mainly as a place in which to turn back communist intrusions for reasons of high policy.
Ignorance of the region compounded the tendency. Those in charge—presidents, secretaries of state, secretaries of defense, national security advisers, CIA directors, and the other inhabitants of the U.S. foreign policy apparatus—never possessed much knowledge and understanding of Latin America. Secretary of state Dean Acheson confessed early in 1950 that he was “rather vague” about its people, unsure “whether they were richer or poorer, going Communist, Fascist or what.” President Truman made comparisons based on ethnic stereotypes, claiming that Latin Americans reminded him of the Jews and the Irish: They were “very emotional” and hard to manage. Later, secretary of state John Foster Dulles claimed to know what to do: “You have to pat them a little bit and make them think you are fond of them.” President Eisenhower acknowledged that he had a fondness for the Argentines because they are “the same kind of people we are.” This kind of condescension at least hinted of racism.
A remarkable memorandum by George F. Kennan revealed something of official perceptions. A senior Foreign Service officer and State Department counselor, Kennan obtained renown as “the father of containment” for his “Mr. X” article, “The Sources of Soviet Conduct,” in Foreign Affairs in July 1947. Early in 1950, he undertook his first journey into Latin America. His subsequent report, “Latin America as a Problem in United States Foreign Policy,” contained his observations. As Gaddis Smith explains, this report had no direct bearing on the formulation of foreign policy but nevertheless qualified as “a seminal document” because it set forth the “Kennan corollary,” following in the tradition of the Richard Olney and Theodore Roosevelt corollaries to Monroe’s original message to Congress and the J. Reuben Clark memorandum. As “an unvarnished statement of widely held attitudes,” it affirmed a rationale for supporting repressive dictatorships when compelled to do so by the requirements of anticommunism.29 Kennan, it should be stressed, had no experience in Latin America comparable to his knowledge of the USSR.
Kennan left Washington, DC, by train on February 18, 1950, on his way to Mexico City and then traveled by plane to Caracas, Rio de Janeiro, São Paulo, Montevideo, Buenos Aires, Lima, and Panama City. What he saw and experienced along the way dismayed and distressed him. In Mexico City, he disliked the altitude and the disturbed, sultry, and menacing sounds of “nocturnal activity.” In Caracas, he reacted against a “feverish economy debauched by oil money.” In Rio, the “noisy, wildly competitive” traffic and “the unbelievable contrasts between luxury and poverty” repelled him. In Lima, he became “depressed” while reflecting “that it had not rained . . . for twenty-nine years.” Overall, his memorandum conveyed an impression of distaste for the people, the leaders, and their countries. In Kennan’s words, “It seemed unlikely that there could be any other region of the earth in which nature and human behavior could have combined to produce a more unhappy and hopeless background for the conduct of human life than in Latin America.” Placing heavy responsibility on the legacies of miscegenation, he wrote, “The handicaps to progress are written in human blood and in the tracings of geography; and in neither case are they readily susceptible of obliteration. They lie heavily across the path of human progress.”30
Kennan nevertheless attached geopolitical importance to Latin America. In a war against the Soviet Union, he feared catastrophic consequences if “a considerable portion of Latin American society were to throw its weight morally into the opposite camp.” Such an association “might well turn the market of international confidence against us and leave us fighting not only communist military power, but a wave of defeatism among our friends and spiteful elation among our detractors elsewhere in the world.” For him, communism in Latin America posed a real threat. “Here, as elsewhere, the inner core of the communist leadership is fanatical, disciplined, industrious, and armed with a series of organizational techniques which are absolutely first rate.”
How could the United States turn back the danger? Kennan found the answer in the Monroe Doctrine: Soviet efforts to make “pawns” of Latin American countries from “beyond the limits of this continent” clearly ran against Monroe’s historic prohibition. The United States needed support from Latin American governments. To enlist it, positive incentives—possibly economic and military aid—could encourage anticommunist measures such as crackdowns on radical agitation. Otherwise, coercion, perhaps diplomatic penalties, could dissuade Latin American governments from engaging in “excessive toleration of anti-American activities.” As Gaddis Smith explains, Kennan saw in Latin America “a political culture too weak and selfish to support a democracy strong enough to resist the superior determination and skill of the Communist enemy.”
The Kennan corollary articulated a basic premise: “We cannot be too dogmatic about the methods by which local communists can be dealt with.” In Kennan’s view, everything depended upon “the vigor and efficacy of local concepts and traditions of self-government.” If these were as sound and reliable “as in our own country,” then “the body politic may be capable of bearing the virus of communism without permitting it to expand to dangerous proportions.” He regarded this approach as “undoubtedly the best solution of the communist problem, wherever the prerequisites exist.” But lacking them, if “the concepts and traditions of popular government are too weak to absorb successfully the intensity of the communist attack,” then “we must concede that harsh governmental measures of repression may be the only answer.” He went on to explain “that these measures may have to proceed from regimes whose origins and methods would not stand the test of American concepts of democratic procedures; and that such regimes and such methods may be preferable alternatives, and indeed the only alternatives to further communist success.” In short, relying on right-wing military dictators as anticommunist bastions was preferable to risking communist advances. Gaddis Smith remarks that Kennan’s position on this matter “is inconsistent with much of his subsequent thought” and attributes it to “the culture shock of a Europeanist who had never visited Latin America before.” During his trip, he experienced “an uncharacteristic susceptibility to the views of the American ambassadors with whom he talked” and to “the near-hysterical sense of a worldwide Communist menace in that year 1950.” His own preference for “realism” over “moralistic rhetoric” also contributed. Nevertheless, and this is the important point, Kennan’s assumptions and observations typified official thinking and undergirded important parts of U.S. policy toward Latin America during the next forty years.31
The Korean conflict intensified apprehension over communist expansion and the possibility of a third world war. The causes, much discussed in historical literature, appeared straightforward to U.S. leaders at the time. In their view, the North Korean invasion of South Korea on June 25, 1950, came about because the Soviet Union had willed it, establishing another case in which totalitarian aggression threatened the freedom of peace-loving nations. Recalling Nazi behavior in the late 1930s, Truman acted upon a set of analogies derived mainly from the Munich conference in 1938. Constituting for him and others of his generation the primary lesson of the Second World War, the Munich analogy set forth a simple proposition: Appeasement in the face of totalitarian aggression never works. Indeed, shows of weakness and irresolution merely invite further aggression. Therefore, democratic nations must stand their ground or subsequently run the risk of bigger wars. Scholars have since questioned Truman’s analysis, asking whether the Munich analogy holds in this instance. Some recent works depict the conflict less as Stalin’s creation than as a consequence of a Korean civil war. North Korean leader Kim Il Sung probably took the initiative on his own to unify the country, and Stalin, for his own reasons, went along. Indeed, some scholars now wonder whether U.S. intervention improved the situation or made it worse.32
Taking the lead, the Truman administration resisted Soviet aggression while working through the Security Council of the United Nations. The United States obtained a resolution urging a cease-fire, the withdrawal of North Korean forces, and the restoration of the status quo ante bellum. When North Korea failed to comply, a second UN resolution called upon members to respond with military support for South Korea. During the next three years, until the armistice on July 27, 1953, the United States supplied most of the ground, air, and naval forces from the outside. Other contingents came from the United Kingdom, Turkey, Greece, the Philippines, and Thailand.33
The countries of Latin America, whose twenty votes constituted two-fifths of those in the General Assembly in 1950, initially backed the United Nations. Moreover, the Organization of American States went on record on June 28, 1950, declaring its “firm adherence to the decisions of the competent organs of the United Nations” and reaffirming “the pledges of continental solidarity which unite the American States.”34 Latin American republics displayed no equivalent readiness to take part in the fighting, however. Only Colombia sent a token force, an infantry battalion, primarily because the dictator, Laureano Gómez, anticipated payoffs from the United States in return.35 U.S. leaders tried to recruit the participation of other Latin American ground forces as a sign of commitment, especially after the Chinese intervention late in 1950. These attempts centered on Bolivia, Chile, Uruguay, Mexico, Peru, and Brazil and failed in each instance. At first, Brazil and Peru indicated some interest but only in return for military and economic subsidies. Most Latin American governments claimed that public opinion in their countries would not accept troop commitments.
The historian William Stueck attributes such “meager results” partly to the fact that Latin America, “a grievously poor region,” lacked “any tradition of direct involvement” in overseas conflicts. Only Mexico and Brazil had sent military contingents abroad during the Second World War. In addition, Latin Americans perceived no communist threat to themselves and resented what they understood as U.S. neglect, specifically the absence of a Marshall Plan. In Stueck’s phrase, “Tired of being taken for granted by their big brother in the north . . . the Latin republics hedged when asked to provide cannon fodder for a U.S. crusade in a remote land.”36
Latin American recalcitrance became apparent at the Fourth Meeting of Consultation of Ministers of Foreign Affairs of the American Republics in Washington from March 26 to April 7, 1951. Summoned by the Truman administration “to consider problems of an urgent nature and of common interest to American States,” and sponsored by the OAS, the conference revealed deep divisions over questions of hemispheric security and economic development. Latin American delegations denied the existence of a communist threat in the Western Hemisphere and argued that in any case, improved living standards sustained by U.S. aid would provide the best means of defense.37 Resisting this appeal, the United States emphasized the military requirements of collective self-defense. Later on in 1951, the U.S. Congress implemented a program under the Mutual Security Act, which authorized the negotiation of “mutual defense assistance agreements” with Latin American countries. Beginning with Ecuador in January 1952, twelve such pacts eventually came into existence. Under the terms first established with Ecuador, the United States agreed to make available “equipment, materials, services, and other military assistance designed to promote the defense and maintain the peace of the Western Hemisphere.” In return, Ecuador would utilize the aid to strengthen its military defenses and, significantly, “to facilitate the production and transfer . . . of . . . strategic materials required by the United States.” From the U.S. standpoint, these provisions contained strong incentives for pact partners to provide adequate supplies of raw materials and to guard against radical subversion. Subsequent military programs also emphasized the training of Latin American officers in “counterinsurgency” techniques, proposing to use them as anticommunist bulwarks.38
In the end, the Korean War destroyed the Truman presidency. Weakened politically by the military inconclusiveness of the conflict, his firing of general Douglas MacArthur, and the spurious Republican allegations of softness on communism, Truman lacked the grounds to present himself in 1952 as a candidate for a second full term. Instead, the Democratic nomination fell to Adlai Stevenson, a former Illinois governor. The Republicans, seeking to gain the presidency for the first time since 1932, took full advantage. Particularly, they assailed the Democrats for perpetuating big government at home and incompetency in foreign policy. Korea supposedly stood as a case in point. While characterizing the Democratic policy of containment as “defensive, negative, futile, and immoral,” the Republicans suggested a more dynamic approach by which to seize the initiative, roll back the communist tide, and win victories in the Cold War.39 Their efforts to advance such goals during Dwight D. Eisenhower’s presidency had many implications for Latin America.
During the 1950s, Cold War issues preoccupied the leaders of the Eisenhower administration in Latin America. Anticommunism, the hallmark of U.S. policy, required order, stability, and constant vigilance against radical subversion. At the same time, Latin American nationalists, reformers, and home-grown revolutionaries blurred distinctions by insisting upon state activity to instigate economic development. For the United States, how to sort them out from Soviet-style communists posed a real dilemma. Other issues also caused difficulties. A critical one centered on trade, or aid, as the best means of moving Latin America toward modernization. Another concerned the utility of intervention by the United States. A clandestine operation in Guatemala in 1954 toppled a popularly elected government that was perceived in Washington as communist-dominated. This short-term success led later to similar efforts against Fidel Castro in Cuba. Looked upon by the United States as a dangerous precedent, Castro’s revolutionary triumph symbolized a repudiation of U.S. tutelage and suggested to the remainder of Latin America the option of following Cuba’s lead.
As depicted by Eisenhower during the 1952 campaign, Truman’s policies in Latin America had gone dangerously wrong. According to Ike, the U.S. had “frantically wooed Latin America” during the Second World War but then “proceeded to forget these countries just as fast” after the peace. Consequently, a “terrible disillusionment set in,” and “Communist agents” who were standing ready “skillfully exploited” economic distress and political unrest for their own purposes. “Through drift and neglect,” the Truman administration had embraced what Ike called “a poor neighbor policy,” now very much in need of a change.40
In an important book on the Eisenhower administration and Latin America, the historian Stephen G. Rabe takes a revisionist stance by arguing that the president “decisively” established and oversaw the policies of his administration. Unlike the earlier body of writing that depicted Eisenhower as a kind of figurehead, the more recent scholarship portrays him as a chief executive truly in charge. According to the political scientist Fred I. Greenstein, Eisenhower often misled observers by employing indirect and obscure methods in a “hidden hand” style of leadership. Operating unobtrusively behind the scenes, he exercised command while allowing subordinates to indulge in appearances.41
In the case of Latin America, Eisenhower moved quickly to institute corrective actions. Within two months of taking office, he approved a statement formulated by the National Security Council, “United States Objectives and Courses of Action with Respect to Latin America.” This document emphasized the necessity of “hemispheric solidarity” against international communism and called for the enlistment of Latin American support in the struggle against the Soviet Union, especially the threat of internal communist subversion. Recalling the requirements of the Kennan corollary, this approach encouraged the administration to embrace anticommunist leaders in Latin America—including repressive dictators—as allies.
Before becoming president, Eisenhower had had modest experience with Latin America. After graduating from the U.S. Military Academy in 1915, while serving at Fort Sam Houston in San Antonio, Texas, he went on hunting trips into Mexico and acquired a “romantic” if somewhat “patronizing attitude” toward Mexicans. In Panama in the early 1920s, he developed a dislike for the tropics and for the blatant forms of discrimination experienced by Panamanians in the Canal Zone. Early in the Second World War, he worked with Lend-Lease programs for Latin America and later paid official visits to Mexico, Panama, and Brazil. In the main, he thought that military aid to Latin America well served U.S. interests in national security.
Eisenhower’s secretary of state, John Foster Dulles, had a reputation as the Republican expert on foreign affairs. As a young man, he had attended the Paris Peace Conference in 1919 in a minor capacity. He built his professional career with the Wall Street law firm of Sullivan and Cromwell, often working out of its Berlin and Paris offices on matters of international investment and finance. In Latin America, he represented U.S. corporations such as the United Fruit Company. Outspoken, acerbic, and assertive, Secretary Dulles played an influential role but never dominated Eisenhower. The “hidden-hand” president allowed subordinates to take credit or blame, depending on his needs, but always kept his own prerogatives intact.
Eisenhower also relied heavily on his youngest brother, Milton Eisenhower, as a source of information on Latin American affairs. Regarded by Ike as “the most knowledgeable and widely informed of all the people with whom I deal,” Milton Eisenhower possessed no particular Latin American expertise but a broad understanding based on a variety of career experiences, including stints as a former Foreign Service officer and an Agriculture Department official. He had also served as the president of Kansas State University, Pennsylvania State University, and Johns Hopkins University. Ike corresponded with his brother regularly and often spent weekends in his company. On two occasions, he sent Milton as a special ambassador on fact-finding missions to Latin America.42
Top Eisenhower leaders were united in the conviction that communism posed a worldwide danger. During his confirmation hearings before the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, Dulles described the “threat” as “the gravest . . . that ever faced the United States,” indeed, “the gravest . . . that has ever faced what we call western civilization, or . . . any civilization which was dominated by a spiritual faith.” In Latin America, in Dulles’s view, communists had penetrated every country. Animated by “hatred of the Yankee,” they sought “to destroy the influence of the so-called Colossus of the North in Central and South America.” Distressed by what he regarded as a disturbing parallel, he claimed that “conditions in Latin America are somewhat comparable to conditions as they were in China in the mid-thirties when the Communist movement was getting started.” Therefore, “the time to deal with this rising menace in South America is now.”
Such rhetoric aptly reflected the administration’s apprehensions. Sometimes Eisenhower and his aides used this kind of language for political effect to rally anticommunists in the Republican party, but in the Latin American case “the private discussions and classified policy statements of administration officials differed little from their public positions.” For example, the president worried about the consequences of surging nationalism in the Third World, identifying it as a cause of instability and a potential vehicle of communist expansion. For Ike, nationalism “on the move” required special wariness. In his diary, attempting to describe “actually what is going on,” he wrote that “communists are hoping to take advantage of the confusion resulting from the destruction of existing relationships and uncertainties of disrupted trade, security, and understanding.” He feared that communists would capitalize on nationalist agitation “to further the aims of world revolution and the Kremlin’s domination of all people.”43
Ike’s critics have suggested that such anxieties, however overdrawn, should have elicited more imaginative reactions. Specifically, the Eisenhower administration should have tried to neutralize communist appeals by mobilizing pro-U.S. nationalist elements with positive incentives. As it turned out, the leaders never attained such creative levels. Their error resided in apprehending third-world nationalism so exclusively in Cold War terms. As a consequence, the historian Robert J. McMahon argues, the Eisenhower administration “grievously misunderstood and underestimated the most significant historical development of the mid-twentieth century.”44
How to distinguish third-world nationalism from Soviet communism remained a principal problem for U.S. policy makers in Latin America throughout the Cold War. Among his primary goals, Eisenhower wanted to secure “the allegiance of these republics in our camp in the cold war.” But he could not tell whether policies to accommodate Latin American nationalists would win them over or open the way to communist advances. In other words, he was unsure how to calculate the effects of meaningful reforms: Would they undercut communist appeals or encourage revolution by disrupting traditional relationships? Dulles, a pessimist in these matters, feared that “the Communists are trying to extend their form of despotism in this hemisphere.” Underscoring what he regarded as the true nature of the threat, he defined communism as “an internationalist conspiracy, not an indigenous movement.” “In the old days,” Dulles claimed, “we used to be able to let South America go through the wringer of bad times . . . but the trouble is now, when you put it through the wringer, it comes out red.”
The National Security Council initiated discussions of these matters in February 1953. Stating the theme, the CIA director Allen Dulles, brother of the secretary of state, spoke of “deteriorating” relations with Latin America, marked by a “Communist infection” in Guatemala, and warned of “an approaching crisis.” A month later, on March 18, 1953, the National Security Council established essential aims in a policy document known as NSC-144/1. As Stephen G. Rabe notes, the planners “interpreted inter-American affairs solely within the context of the global struggle with the Soviet Union.” Essentially, the Eisenhower administration wanted four things from Latin America: support in the United Nations, eradication of “internal Communist or other anti-U.S. subversion,” access to strategic raw materials, and military cooperation in defending the hemisphere. Yet the document demonstrated scant faith in the reliability of Latin American leaders and their capacity to comprehend the international danger. NSC-144/1 disparaged as “immature and impractical idealists” such influential figures as Lázaro Cárdenas in Mexico, Juan José Arévalo in Guatemala, José Figueres in Costa Rica, Rómulo Betancourt in Venezuela, Víctor Raúl Haya de la Torre in Peru, and Getúlio Vargas in Brazil. It asserted that these men were “inadequately trained to conduct government business efficiently,” lacked “the disposition to combat extremists within their ranks, including communists,” and displayed a Latin American penchant for “irresponsible acts.” Much like the Kennan corollary, NSC-144/1 invoked “overriding security interests” as a justification for U.S. intervention. Whenever necessary, the United States should employ unilateral measures, even if they might violate “our treaty commitments, . . . endanger the Organization of American States . . . and . . . probably intensify anti-U.S. attitudes in many Latin American countries.”
The anticommunist campaign in Latin America also employed political propaganda and military aid. According to Rabe, the U.S. Information Agency spent $5.2 million a year in such efforts to get out the message as, for example, the production and distribution of comic books, cartoon strips, and movie shorts. Intended for mass consumption, these devices warned of totalitarian threats menacing the freedom and property of individuals. Sometimes they elicited faulty inferences; in Mexico, some audiences reportedly thought the danger emanated from their own government. Anticommunist initiatives placed special importance on Latin American trade unions. The military establishments also received special treatment. Viewed by U.S. leaders as anticommunist bulwarks, Latin American armies became the recipients of increased military aid. Rabe questions whether “the strategic benefits of inter-American military cooperation” really amounted to much. At the same time, he acknowledges that “the political advantages of military aid” were “significant,” especially when training and assistance programs gave access to the dominant military caste. Military officers wielded power in so many of the countries that U.S. leaders regarded shows of support for them as essential. In dealings with Juan Perón’s Argentine government, for example, Cold War considerations ultimately overcame earlier suspicions of his pro-fascism.
As staunch anticommunists, Eisenhower officials displayed no equivalent devotion to democracy and human rights. Some thought the defense of such values might violate the nonintervention principle or, worse, incite radicalism and subversion. Others shared Milton Eisenhower’s misimpression. After a trip to South America in the fall of 1953 the president’s brother reported with stunning inaccuracy that “most American nations which still have degrees of feudalism and dictatorship are moving gradually toward democratic concepts and practices.” As Rabe observes, military dictators at the time controlled thirteen Latin American republics and enjoyed many favors from the Eisenhower administration. Indeed, two military strongmen, Manuel Odría of Peru and Marcos Pérez Jiménez of Venezuela, received from the United States a special award for foreign leaders called the Legion of Merit citation. After all, as Rabe notes, “Communists, not dictators, were the enemies of the United States.”45
The Guatemalan intervention in 1954 destroyed whatever remained of the Good Neighbor policy. In conformance with the Kennan corollary, Eisenhower officials aided in the overthrow of a government perceived as procommunist. Whether they overreacted or not has occasioned some debate. Most historians have taken a critical stance. Some have emphasized the importance of confusion and misperception: Typically, Eisenhower and his advisers had trouble distinguishing between nationalist reform and communist subversion. Others have perceived a conscious design: To safeguard capitalist interests against radical threats, the United States reverted to interventionist techniques.46
Among the Western Hemisphere nations, Guatemala ranked high in misery and hopelessness. The masses of people, descended from the native Mayas, suffered oppression, poverty, and illiteracy; the effects included disease, malnutrition, high infant mortality, and low life expectancy. In contrast, a small, landed elite monopolized political power and economic advantage, usually with the support of army officers and foreign corporations. The United Fruit Company, owned by U.S. investors, was the biggest property holder and employer in the country. It also dominated transportation and communications. Traditionally, military strongmen, or caudillos, upheld order and authority on behalf of elite interests. From 1931 until 1944, the dictator Jorge Ubico y Castañeda governed with repressive efficiency. Under his criminal code, death was the penalty for union organizers. Laws supposedly intended to curb vagrancy compelled the rural poor to labor in public works projects in circumstances close to slavery. Ubico, a self-styled Napoleon figure, displayed an exhibitionist need for regal uniforms and public displays. A riding accident had rendered him impotent when he was a young man. Nevertheless, in later shows of prowess, he went into the cages at the Guatemala City zoo to roar at the lions.47
Ubico fled the country late in 1944 following an urban-based uprising among middle-class elements: disenchanted schoolteachers, shopkeepers, students, lawyers, and junior military officers. Inspired by Allied ideals during the Second World War and the Mexican example under Lázaro Cárdenas, they joined in marches, demonstrations, and strikes to demand democracy and modernization. An honest election in 1945, probably the first in the country’s history, resulted in the victory of Juan José Arévalo, who won 85 percent of the votes cast by literate adult males. A professor of literature and philosophy and a longtime enemy of Ubico, Arévalo had fled into exile in Argentina in 1935. Back in Guatemala after a decade, he found appalling conditions. The majority of people, mainly agricultural workers, earned less than $100 a year; 2 percent of the population owned 70 percent of the land. Backwardness pervaded the rural regions. Hardly any industry existed at all. More than half of the people were illiterate, including almost all the native peoples.
During a six-year term in office, Arévalo fashioned for Guatemala a reformist program reminiscent of the New Deal in the United States. Among other things, it extended voting rights to all adults, abolished forced labor, instituted minimum wages and collective bargaining for workers, redistributed small amounts of land confiscated from Germans during the war, established a social security agency, and launched a literacy campaign. Predictably, members of the privileged elite opposed these changes. In the course of his presidency, Arévalo survived more than twenty attempts to overthrow him.
Nevertheless, a legal election produced a peaceful transition in March 1951, when Jacobo Árbenz Guzmán took over as president. A professional soldier, a graduate of the Guatemalan military academy, and the secretary of defense under Arévalo, Árbenz “accelerated the pace of change in Guatemala.” In his inaugural address, he promised to build an independent, modern, capitalist state. Later, his efforts to improve the economic infrastructure through the construction of ports and highways trespassed upon the United Fruit Company’s control of such facilities. Similarly, he offended elite interests by supporting an income tax and land reform. Described as “the centerpiece of his program,” Árbenz’s agrarian reform bill sought to advance progress and modernization by redistributing land more equitably to rural workers. One controversial provision authorized the expropriation of uncultivated portions of large estates, in many instances as much as 75 percent of the land controlled by these plantations. Between 1952 and 1954 the Árbenz government disbursed 1.5 million acres to 100,000 families. As Rabe notes, this reform operated well within “the boundaries set by twentieth-century reform movements in the West.” Nevertheless, “the process and pattern of change in Guatemala” collided with the interests of the United Fruit Company.
Based in Boston, United Fruit had operated in Guatemala since the late nineteenth century. Tight linkages connected the company with the traditional ruling elites. Under Ubico the company supported the regime and received tax concessions and vast tracts of land. It owned 550,000 acres, about 85 percent uncultivated, supposedly for reasons of crop rotation and soil conservation. When the Árbenz government initiated expropriation proceedings, offering compensation at three dollars an acre in government bonds, company officials rejected the terms. Instead, they appealed to the Eisenhower administration, claiming that communists had taken over in Guatemala and threatened the Western Hemisphere.48
Much as expected, Eisenhower officials responded sympathetically. Indeed, similar suspicions had percolated through the State Department for some time. In 1949, the Assistant Secretary of State for Inter-American Affairs, Edward G. Miller, Jr., had warned of bad effects if Guatemala threatened the properties of United Fruit. In the same year, U.S. ambassador to Guatemala Richard Patterson pledged his personal opposition to the “cancerous doctrine” of the communists. With “undivided attention,” he would protect “American interests.” He also advised company leaders to employ “an all-out barrage” to win support in the U.S. Senate. Gaddis Smith describes Patterson as a “hysterical, paranoic anti-Communist.” Guatemalan officials regarded his undiplomatic behavior in their country as a form of intervention. In response, Patterson quit his job in the spring of 1950, claiming that communists planned to kill him.
Relations deteriorated further after Árbenz’s inauguration in March 1951. The U.S. government expressed displeasure by means of economic pressure, cuts in foreign aid, and attempts to block the Guatemalan purchase of European military and industrial goods. The United Fruit Company encouraged direct action. In February 1952, company officials characterized “communist infiltration in Guatemala” as “a modern day violation of the Monroe Doctrine.” Guatemalans, however, professed bewilderment. As foreign minister Guillermo Toriello told secretary of state Dean Acheson in the fall of 1952, his government merely wanted “to remove the evils” that had allowed communist sympathies to develop in the first place.
Covert military action was one way of dealing with Árbenz. The Truman administration considered it but held back. According to Gaddis Smith, Truman and Acheson adhered somewhat more literally than their successors to the nonintervention principle as “one of the very keystones of the Inter-American system.”49 Such inhibitions counted for less in the Eisenhower administration. As Supreme Allied Commander in Europe during the Second World War, Ike had become enamored of clandestine operations, particularly the exploits of “Wild Bill” Donovan and the Office of Strategic Services (OSS). Moreover, his administration could point to an actual success. In 1953 the CIA carried out a covert action in Iran: It ousted Mohammed Mossadegh’s nationalist government for expropriating the holdings of U.S. and British oil companies and returned to power a more pliable figure, the Shah Reza Pahlavi.50
The Iranian venture reinforced fundamental assumptions within the administration. In the Guatemalan case, Ike and Dulles invested more faith in the workability of the Kennan corollary than in the principle of nonintervention. Republican leaders also regarded the Democratic version of the containment policy as too passive. During the 1952 campaign the Republicans supported a “New Look” in foreign affairs, advocating a more active approach. By seizing the initiative, they would roll back the communist tide and win victories in the Cold War. Otherwise, Dulles feared, “we might well wake up ten years from now to find that our friends in Latin America had become our enemies.”
Covert action in this instance brought about the overthrow of the Árbenz regime and the establishment of the kind of government anticipated by Kennan: harsh, repressive, and undemocratic. As Gaddis Smith explains, this undertaking, “one of the most minutely studied in the history of U.S.-Latin American relations,” followed three tracks: economic pressure, collective action through the Organization of American States, and a clandestine operation using anti-Árbenz rebels organized by the CIA in Honduras. Historians’ interpretations have established different points of emphasis: a determination to defend U.S. corporate interests, the influence of anticommunism, the role of misperception, and the presumed necessity of standing strong in the Cold War struggle. But all agree on the effects. The Guatemalan intervention in 1954 closed down Franklin Roosevelt’s Good Neighbor policy for keeps.51
At the Tenth Inter-American Conference at Caracas, Venezuela, in March 1954, Dulles hoped to obtain multilateral support for measures against Guatemala but failed to get it. Latin Americans again differed with the United States over priorities and preferences. They wanted open discussions of economic issues focused on trade, aid, and the like, whereas the U.S. delegates insisted on the primacy of security matters and pushed for an anticommunist resolution. It declared that “the domination or control of the political institutions of any American state by the international communist movement . . . would constitute a threat” to regional security, therefore necessitating “appropriate action in accordance with existing treaties.” This statement, a reference to the Rio Pact of 1947, specifically article 6, had procedural implications. It meant that a two-thirds majority among the OAS members would have to agree to take action against “an aggression which was not an armed attack,” either by means of economic sanctions or a joint intervention. In conformance with the Kennan corollary, Dulles really wanted to extend “the Monroe Doctrine to include the concept of outlawing foreign ideologies in the American Republics.”
The leaders in the Eisenhower administration wanted a demonstration for Latin Americans to illustrate the incompatibility of communism with nationalism. In the U.S. view, no conceivable mix was possible; therefore, communism in Guatemala constituted subversion, not reform. To counter it, the leaders contemplated drastic measures. A State Department memorandum circulating among U.S. diplomats in Latin America suggested the feasibility of a unilateral intervention. If Latin Americans refused to accept their responsibility to police the Western Hemisphere against communist incursions, so the reasoning went, then the United States would have no choice except to reassess “the soundness of the OAS relationship,” perhaps by taking action alone.
At Caracas, Dulles pressed the anticommunist case during two weeks of debate. In the course of it, he urged immediate action and fought off fifty amendments proposed by Latin Americans. In the end, he got a resolution but not the one he wanted. Passed by a vote of 17 to 1 (Guatemala opposed), with Mexico and Argentina abstaining, the measure in Dulles’s view lacked “vitality.” Instead of calling for immediate action against the communist threat in Guatemala, the OAS advised in favor of future deliberations to consider the means of upholding treaty obligations. As Rabe notes, by employing the ancient tactics of procrastination and delay, “the Latin Americans rejected the administration’s contention that communism in Latin America constituted external aggression.”52 At no point during the ensuing Guatemalan intervention could the United States count unambiguously on Latin American support.
Nevertheless, the plan for covert action got under way. In the middle of May a Swedish vessel, the Alfhem, arrived in Guatemala with a cargo of arms from communist Czechoslovakia. Presented as proof of communist complicity with Guatemalan officials, this event enabled Secretary Dulles to issue another indictment of “Communist penetration” of the Western Hemisphere. Soon thereafter a clandestine operation supported by the United States successfully eliminated the offending Árbenz regime from power. A small rebel army of two hundred began the invasion of Guatemala on June 18, 1954, by moving across the Honduran border. Recruited and trained by the CIA, this force, commanded by lieutenant colonel Carlos Castillo Armas, was incapable of waging war against the much larger Guatemalan army; instead, it utilized indirect methods. As Allen Dulles reported to President Eisenhower, the success of the venture depended more on “psychological impact” than on “actual military strength.” Nevertheless, Dulles wanted to create “the impression of very substantial military strength” through the use of deception and disinformation. Fake radio reports of large-scale fighting instilled panic and demoralization, and a real but small-scale bombing raid against Guatemala City produced hysteria.
The effects unhinged President Árbenz. Unsure of the reliability of his own army, he feared the possibility of U.S. military action. Reportedly influenced by strong drink, he resigned on June 27 and fled into exile, leaving the government to a military junta. For a week, army officers jockeyed for position. Then on July 2, under U.S. pressure, they settled on Colonel Castillo Armas, also the CIA’s favorite choice. As head of state, Castillo Armas instituted a series of anticommunist measures, nullified Árbenz’s reforms, and restored the old regime. The consequences were political polarization and civil war. During the next four decades, more than 250,000 Guatemalans died in the ongoing violence. Carlos Castillo Armas was one of them; assassins gunned him down in 1957. Throughout Latin America, the reactions were mixed. In the countries where dictators had control, official responses suggested at least a readiness to acquiesce in the U.S. intervention. But critics and protesters in Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Cuba, Ecuador, Mexico, and Uruguay condemned the United States for what they called aggression against Guatemala, indicating at the very least their displeasure with the application of the Kennan corollary in their part of the world.53 The supposed geopolitical imperatives of the Cold War held less importance for them than questions of economic growth and modernization.
As Stephen G. Rabe shows, Latin American leaders in the 1950s typically looked upon the inter-American system less as an anticommunist alliance than as “a mechanism for economic cooperation.”54 They wanted programs of economic assistance from the United States and ultimately compelled the Eisenhower administration to grapple with tough questions of trade or aid. During Ike’s first term, U.S. officials expressed preferences for trade over aid as the primary engine of economic progress but shifted ground grudgingly during his second term, thereby allowing for a possibility of discussing both.
Ike’s economic views conformed with convention by regarding free trade and private investment as the main requisites for peace and prosperity. Eisenhower regarded mass poverty, hunger, and insecurity as threats, that is, as incitements to the spread of communism. He believed that free enterprise could best advance the collective well-being: It would “allow backward people to make a decent living—even if only a minimum one measured by American standards,” and the United States would also benefit. In his diary, he underscored the importance of ready access to raw materials—tin, cobalt, uranium, manganese, crude oil—and noted that “unless the areas in which these materials are found are under the control of people who are friendly to us and who want to trade with us, then . . . we are bound in the long run to suffer the most disastrous and doleful consequences.”
As a self-styled fiscal conservative, Eisenhower fretted over the excesses of government spending, yet between 1953 and 1961 his administration granted or lent nearly $50 billion in military and economic aid to other countries. But for him, such programs had limited applicability; as he told his brother Milton, they pertained only to those regions directly imperiled by “the Communist menace.” Consequently, Latin America ranked low in priority. On March 18, 1953, the National Security Council in NSC-144/1 confirmed this view with a statement of expectations. Latin American governments would have to learn that if private enterprise could best supply “the capital required for their economic development,” then “their own self-interest requires the creation of a climate which will attract private investment.” The same admonitions appeared in November 1953 in Milton Eisenhower’s report of his fact-finding tour to South America. Subsequently regarded as orthodox and unimaginative even by the author, it expressed views that unsurprisingly favored fiscal responsibility, “honest money,” and balanced budgets over other approaches featuring economic nationalism, “industrialization for its own sake,” and “creeping expropriation.” For their own good, Milton Eisenhower exhorted Latin Americans to uphold the principle of free trade and the sanctity of foreign investments and to understand that private monies “must be attracted by the nation desiring the capital.” Such banalities amused Brazilian diplomats, who wondered why Milton Eisenhower had to make a trip to Latin American to arrive at these conclusions.
In the State Department, assistant secretary John Moors Cabot developed doubts about them. He had accompanied Milton Eisenhower on the tour and drew some bleaker inferences. In much of Latin America, he reported, per capita income was about one-eighth that of the United States. In the poorest countries—Bolivia, Ecuador, and Haiti—the situation was even worse. Yet the United States sent only about 1 percent of its economic development assistance to Latin America, and Cabot warned, “We cannot indefinitely continue the present discrimination against our sister republics in this hemisphere without gravely prejudicing our relations with them.” Moreover, he placed scant faith in the capacity of private investment to solve the problem. In his view, a variety of impediments obstructed economic advancement, including inadequate transportation and communication systems, multitudes of impoverished people who lacked educational and technical skills, and vast disparities of wealth and power with the upper classes exercising “an almost feudal control.” For all these reasons, he concluded, “trickle-down” economics would neither produce great bursts of economic growth nor nullify communist appeals.
As a place to begin, Cabot suggested modest increases in developmental loans, relying primarily on the Export-Import Bank to support the improvement of infrastructure. In response, secretary of the treasury George Humphrey, an ideologue, took offense at the heresy. Devoutly combative in his fiscal conservatism, Humphrey demanded that Latin Americans conform with history and tradition by adhering to the developmental model of the United States. For him, this approach meant reliance on private foreign capital. Secretary of State Dulles supported Cabot’s ideas but not Cabot. Convinced that boom-and-bust cycles increased Latin American vulnerability to communist insinuation, Dulles secured the president’s consent for the use of the Export-Import Bank in support of “sound development projects.” He also agreed to take part in a long-deferred Latin American economic conference. Nevertheless, he punished Cabot for pushing too hard. The assistant secretary lost his job and went off to Stockholm as the ambassador to Sweden.
More bureaucratic wrangling occurred as plans developed for the economic conference, scheduled to begin in Rio de Janeiro late in November 1954. As head of the U.S. delegation, secretary of the treasury George Humphrey predictably favored trade, not aid, but on this occasion the president differed with him. Ike, as it turned out, had agreed to expand the operations of the Export-Import Bank in Latin America and to increase its overall lending capacity by $500 million. This move ranked as “the only significant initiative” by the United States at the conference. It also conformed with the administration’s understanding of Cold War imperatives. As Ike explained to Humphrey, U.S. policy in Latin America was “chiefly designed to play a part in the cold war against our enemies.” Extraordinary measures had become necessary because the “United States was not merely doing ‘business’ in Latin America, but was fighting a war there against Communism.”
Latin Americans had hoped for more. According to the Brazilian ambassador, João Carlos Muniz, government leaders had believed ever since the Second World War that “the vast resources of the United States were going to be brought to bear on wide and rapid economic change in Latin America.” But delay and inaction has caused “an intense process of disillusionment.” Brazilians could not understand why the United States used large-scale programs of economic aid and assistance in the fight against communism in Asia and Europe but depended upon “politico-police” methods in the Western Hemisphere.55 Evolving Latin American economic theories dissented from the established orthodoxies in the United States. Latin Americans depicted free markets and private investments as failures in their part of the Western Hemisphere. Such practices simply had not worked. Instead of diffusing growth, progress, and modernization throughout the region, free trade and private investment had locked Latin America into conditions of economic dependency and underdevelopment. In other words, they perpetuated an inequitable economic system based on neocolonial relationships.
For Latin Americans, integration into the world capitalist system meant dependence on market fluctuations in Europe and the United States, entailing extreme vulnerability in times of economic downswing. Their experience during the two world wars and the Great Depression appeared as cases in point. Moreover, Latin Americans operated at a disadvantage because of the terms of exchange. As producers of primary commodities, they provided the industrialized world with low-cost agricultural products and mineral resources and purchased in return high-cost manufactured goods. The very structure of the transaction placed them at a disadvantage and enabled foreign interests to exercise control over their economic destinies. Indeed, as described by the Argentine economist Raúl Prebisch, the situation was getting worse. The cost of manufactured products had increased steadily in comparison with the prices obtained for raw materials and agricultural goods. For a decade after 1952 the combined price index of commodities sold by Latin Americans—coffee, wheat, corn, tin, cotton, sisal, lead, zinc, nitrates, sugar—declined in every year except one.56
For many Latin Americans, the impact of traditional trade and investment practices helped account for the poor performance of their economies. The statistics were disheartening. In the early 1950s, annual per capita income in Latin America amounted to $250; life expectancy was forty-three years; and an expanding population eroded whatever gains might come about in productivity. Structural considerations contributing to the difficulties included unresponsive and unstable political systems, a maldistribution of wealth and land, insufficient economic infrastructure, inadequate educational systems, and indifference among the ruling elites.
The dimensions of the problem became clearer in a series of studies by the Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA), a UN agency headed by Prebisch. These reports described shortages of investment capital for economic development as the chief deficiency and accounted for them by tracking the flow of money in and out of Latin America. According to Prebisch, the economic outlays in Latin America—that is, interest payments and profit remittances on public loans and private investments—exceeded the inputs. In other words, the advanced countries took more money out than they put in. As a consequence, economic growth was calculated at 1 percent a year. To enhance it, ECLA economists estimated that Latin America needed $1 billion a year for ten years, most of which would have to come from international lending institutions and the United States.
U.S. traders and investors already played an enormous role in Latin American economies. By the early 1950s, their investments in Latin America ran to $6 billion, about 40 percent of direct U.S. investments in the world. Most of the money went into extractive industries such as Chilean copper and Venezuelan oil. Annual trade between the United States and Latin America amounted to $7 billion, the overall balance slightly favoring the United States. Latin America accounted for 25 percent of U.S. international trade.
In these circumstances, Latin Americans still looked to the United States for assistance. In anticipation of the Rio economic conference from November 22 to December 2, 1954, Ambassador Muniz expressed his hope for “great things.” Specifically, he wanted an Eisenhower Plan for Latin America, presumably something like the Marshall Plan for Western Europe. But his hopes failed to materialize. U.S. leaders rejected any such approach as inconsistent with established policies, priorities, and preferences; they favored free trade and private investment. During the conference the U.S. delegation made a small concession by agreeing to expand the lending authority of the Export-Import Bank but otherwise provided no satisfaction for Latin Americans. As Rabe remarks, “By intervening in Guatemala and by ignoring Latin America’s economic needs,” the Eisenhower administration appeared to endorse the “attitudes and practices” of an earlier time.57
After the Korean armistice on July 27, 1953, the United States enjoyed a period of peace and prosperity. Eisenhower won reelection in 1956, following a campaign in which Latin America figured hardly at all. The main policy tenets—anticommunism, free trade, and private investment—persisted into the second term, as did the practice of supporting military dictators. Though privately a bit ambivalent about the matter, Eisenhower usually evaded questions concerned with civil liberties and human rights. In all likelihood the president would have preferred the existence of more democratic regimes and on occasion may have maneuvered behind the scenes to curb abuses. When Juan Perón fell from power in 1955, Ike expressed his approval. At the same time, he embraced military strongmen as necessary allies in the anti-communist struggle. By the mid-1950s, military aid in Latin America was one of the costliest budget items in the region. Ike understood that Latin American forces possessed scant fighting ability. Yet he wanted not only “to preserve . . . the good will of the Latin American Republics” but also “to assure their internal security, without which their good will would be useless to us.” As Rabe concludes, “The transfer of arms and the training of Latin American officers and soldiers continued, because the administration wanted powerful, anti-Communist friends in Latin America.”
Also in the mid-1950s, changes in the Soviet Union caused mounting concern. Following Stalin’s death in March 1953 the aspiring heirs engaged in a complex power struggle in which foreign policy played a role. An early claimant to Stalin’s position, Nikolai Bulganin, offered in January 1956 to expand diplomatic, economic, and cultural relations with Latin America, especially through trade and technical assistance. As part of a larger Soviet effort in the Third World, Bulganin’s initiatives anticipated more effective forms of peaceful competition. But in Latin America, they accomplished almost nothing. As consumers, Latin Americans regarded Soviet merchandise as shoddy and unattractive. Moreover, they disliked the brutal Soviet suppression of the Hungarian uprising during the fall of 1956. Consequently, Secretary Dulles arrived at the comforting conclusion in 1957 that “we see no likelihood at the present time of communism getting into control of the political institutions of any of the American Republics.”
Anticommunist apprehensions escalated in 1958 following vice president Richard M. Nixon’s disastrous visit to South America, which produced protests, riots, and a life-threatening mob scene. First conceived by Roy Richard Rubottom, then serving as the assistant secretary of state for Latin American affairs, the plan envisioned the trip as a goodwill gesture, conveying to Latin Americans some new readiness to address economic issues. Rubottom had worried late in 1957 that “the economic situation in the whole area has deteriorated” and that communists would take advantage. He suggested that Dulles lead the delegation, but the secretary begged off, claiming other responsibilities. Eisenhower then sent Nixon.
Unenthusiastic about his assignment, Nixon went to Latin America grudgingly late in April 1958. The schedule called for a stop in Argentina to attend the inauguration of president Arturo Frondizi and for others in Uruguay, Peru, and Venezuela. In Montevideo and Lima, Nixon encountered hecklers, and in Caracas, even worse. Earlier that year, Venezuelans had ousted Marcos Pérez Jiménez, a dictator formerly cultivated by the United States. Now they vented their anger against Nixon with menacing demonstrations. As he moved through the streets, they even threatened his life directly by attacking his car before the driver sped away to safety. Nixon later described this event as one of the six crises shaping his political character.
These incidents elicited a new round of debate among Eisenhower officials. Nixon blamed communist agitators, but others had different views. CIA director Allen Dulles found no evidence of linkages with Moscow and reasoned “there would be trouble in Latin America [even] if there were no Communists.”58 Nevertheless, both houses of the U.S. Congress launched inquiries, and Eisenhower sent his brother Milton on a second fact-finding tour, this time to Central America. Such concerns, as Rabe explains, “merged into a wider debate in 1958 about the United States’ position in the world and the quality of President Eisenhower’s leadership.” One source of high anxiety was the Russian Sputnik, a satellite placed in orbit around the earth late in 1957, which immediately took on military and strategic implications. A Soviet missile capable of such a feat also presumably could hit targets in the United States. Other Cold War crises in Lebanon, in Berlin, and in Asia (over the islands of Quemoy and Matsu) kept tensions high. Finally, a crowning blow, the U.S. economy went into recession. Unemployment rose, production fell, and so did Eisenhower’s popularity. Later, Ike described the year 1958 as one of the worst of his life.59
These events produced modest changes in Latin American policy. Notably, while retaining the emphasis on military assistance, the administration displayed somewhat more readiness to support political democracy and human rights. To an extent, this shift made a virtue of necessity. Between 1956 and 1960, ten military dictatorships in Latin America tumbled from power. Corrupt and incompetent, they had provided neither political stability nor economic growth. Tad Szulc, a journalist, referred to the process as “the twilight of the tyrants.” Eisenhower leaders, although they responded with more enthusiastic defenses of representative government, still regarded military establishments as valuable anticommunist allies. In 1959–1960, assistance programs in Latin America expanded, providing more than $160 million in military aid.60
The administration also accepted modest changes in economic policy. In part because of Nixon’s misadventure, in-house critics became more persuasive, especially those who feared that collapsing dictatorships might precipitate revolutions. Such critics included the president’s brother Milton and State Department officials Rubottom, Thomas Mann, and C. Douglas Dillon. Among the Latin American leaders, Juscelino Kubitschek, a former state governor of Minas Gerais and president of Brazil from 1956 until 1961, pressed especially hard. Embracing the slogan “Fifty years of progress in five” and seeking dramatic results, he intended to stimulate economic growth by the unorthodox means of government action based on deficit spending. He also instituted a national development program for building infrastructure, roads and railroads, and created new state enterprises such as an automobile industry. Most spectacularly, he built a new capital city, opening up the interior and symbolizing the advance of progress. Brasília, a showplace, attracted world attention because of its advanced architectural conceptions. But the high costs of such endeavors also had negative consequences, notably, high levels of debilitating inflation.
Two weeks after the anti-Nixon riot in Caracas, Kubitschek called for a “thorough revision” of U.S. programs. Cleverly linking economic development with presumed Cold War imperatives, Kubitschek wanted a solution to “the problem of underdevelopment” so that Latin American nations could “more effectively resist subversion and serve the Western cause.” Specifically, he suggested a pledge of $40 billion from the United States to aid Latin America during the next twenty years. Called Operation Pan America, Kubitschek’s plan, if accepted, would have established an equivalent of the Marshall Plan.
U.S. officials withheld endorsement from anything so grandiose, but they did display new readiness to take part in commodity agreements to stop falling prices for coffee and other such goods. In addition, in August 1958 they announced U.S. support for a regional development bank in Latin America, resulting in the creation of the Inter-American Development Bank in October 1960. These modifications implied “a moderate shift in the administration’s philosophical approach toward Latin America.” But many traditional commitments remained firm; as indicated by NSC-5902/1 in February 1959, the administration still sought the expansion of trade and investment, the promotion of capitalism, and the exclusion of economic nationalism. At the same time, the leaders embraced a new objective, endorsing the view that “Latin America is and must be dealt with primarily as an underdeveloped area.” To accommodate rising levels of expectation, the United States must encourage free enterprise but with recognition of a need to adapt “to local conditions.” Such shifts implied hardly any fundamental change. Administration leaders anticipated only modest expenditures in Latin America through the Inter-American Development Bank. They still believed that progress in Latin America depended upon private enterprise.61
There remained deep divisions over basic issues. For U.S. leaders the inter-American system served national security interests as an anticommunist alliance in defense of order, stability, and the Monroe Doctrine. For the Latin Americans the main rationale took other forms. They wanted regional devices to contain U.S. intervention and to facilitate economic aid and assistance. The absence of a Marshall Plan for the Western Hemisphere disenchanted Latin American leaders, widened the political fissures, and undermined the security apparatus. The shifts that developed during Ike’s last two years never had much impact and, in the U.S. view, the circumstances worsened significantly when Fidel Castro took over in Cuba. This event marked the most significant change in the Americas since the Mexican Revolution and established the foremost issues of the next thirty years.
1. Irwin F. Gellman, Good Neighbor Diplomacy: United States Policies in Latin America, 1933–1945 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979), 179; Gellman, Secret Affairs: Franklin Roosevelt, Cordell Hull, and Sumner Welles (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995), chaps. 13–14.
2. Enthusiasts include J. Lloyd Mecham, The United States and Inter-American Security, 1889–1960 (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1961), chaps. 9–10; Gordon Connell-Smith, The Inter-American System (New York: Oxford University Press, 1966), chaps. 6–7; and Robert Freeman Smith, “U.S. Policy-Making for Latin America Under Truman,” Continuity: A Journal of History 16 (Fall 1992): 87–111. Critics include Lloyd C. Gardner, Economic Aspects of New Deal Diplomacy (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1964), chap. 10; and David Green, The Containment of Latin America: A History of the Myths and Realities of the Good Neighbor Policy (Chicago: Quadrangle Books, 1971), chaps. 7–9.
3. Gellman, Good Neighbor Diplomacy, 191–93; R. A. Humphreys, Latin America and the Second World War, 2 vols. (London: University of London Athlone Press, 1982), 2, chap. 6; Randall Bennett Woods, The Roosevelt Foreign-Policy Establishment and the “Good Neighbor”: The United States and Argentina, 1941–1945 (Lawrence: Regents Press of Kansas, 1979), chaps. 1–3.
4. Gellman, Good Neighbor Diplomacy, 196–97.
5. Gellman, Good Neighbor Diplomacy, chap. 14; Gaddis Smith, The Last Years of the Monroe Doctrine, 1945–1993 (New York: Hill and Wang, 1994), 44.
6. Stephen G. Rabe, “The Elusive Conference: United States Economic Relations with Latin America, 1945–1952,” Diplomatic History 2 (Summer 1978): 279; Humphreys, Latin America, 2, chap. 8.
7. Humphreys, Latin America, 215, chap. 2.
8. Rabe, “Elusive Conference,” 281–82.
9. Humphreys, Latin America, 216–17, chap. 2.
10. Smith, Last Years, 43, 48–49, 55; Humphreys, Latin America, 220–21, chap. 2.
11. Walter LaFeber, America, Russia, and the Cold War, 1945–1992, 7th ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1993), chap. 1; Howard Jones and Randall B. Woods, “Origins of the Cold War in Europe and the New East: Recent Historiography and the National Security Imperative,” in America in the World: The Historiography of American Foreign Relations since 1941, ed. Michael J. Hogan (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995), chap. 9.
12. Smith, Last Years, 56.
13. Thomas G. Paterson and Dennis Merrill, eds., Major Problems in American Foreign Relations, 2 vols., 4th ed. (Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath, 1995), 259–61, chap. 2.
14. Smith, Last Years, 56.
15. Roger R. Trask, “The Impact of the Cold War on United States-Latin American Relations, 1945–1949,” Diplomatic History 1 (Summer 1977): 277.
16. Trask, “The Impact of the Cold War,” 274; Trask, “Spruille Braden versus George Messersmith: World War II, the Cold War, and Argentine Policy, 1945–1947,” Journal of Inter-American Studies and World Affairs 26 (February 1984): 69–95; Jesse H. Stiller, George S. Messersmith: Diplomat of Democracy (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1987), chap. 7.
17. Trask, “Impact of the Cold War,” 277–79; Smith, Last Years, 58–59.
18. Trask, “Impact of the Cold War,” 277–78; Rabe, “Elusive Conference,” 285.
19. Smith, Last Years, 62.
20. Trask, “Impact of the Cold War,” 279–80.
21. Stephen J. Randall, Colombia and the United States: Hegemony and Interdependence (Athens: University of Georgia Press, 1992), 192–94; Trask, “Impact of the Cold War,” 281–82. See also Herbert Braun, The Assassination of Gaitán: Public Life and Urban Violence in Colombia. (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1986).
22. Trask, “Impact of the Cold War,” 281–82.
23. O. Carlos Stoetzer, The Organization of American States, 2d ed. (Westport, CT: Praeger, 1993), 35.
24. Leslie Bethell and Ian Roxborough, “Latin America between the Second World War and the Cold War: Some Reflections on the 1945–8 Conjuncture,” Journal of Latin American Studies 20 (May 1988): 167–89.
25. Leslie Bethell and Ian Roxborough, eds., Latin America between the Second World War and the Cold War: Crisis and Containment, 1944–1948 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 1–2.
26. Bethell and Roxborough, eds., Latin America, 1–7, 10–20, 22–23, 26–28.
27. LaFeber, America, Russia, and the Cold War, 96.
28. Smith, Last Years, 66; LaFeber, America, Russia, and the Cold War, 96–97; Ernest R. May, ed., American Cold War Strategy: Interpreting NSC 68 (Boston: St. Martin’s Press, 1993).
29. Smith, Last Years, 61, 67–68.
30. Roger R. Trask, “George F. Kennan’s Report on Latin America (1950),” Diplomatic History 2 (Summer 1978): 307–11.
31. Smith, Last Years, 69–71.
32. Bruce Cummings, The Origins of the Korean War, 2 vols. (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1981, 1990) states a revisionist case. Burton I. Kaufman, The Korean War: Challenges in Crisis, Credibility, and Command (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1986); and William W. Stueck, The Korean War: An International History (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995), take more traditional approaches.
33. Stueck, Korean War, 194.
34. Gordon Connell-Smith, The United States and Latin America: An Historical Analysis of Inter-American Relations (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1974).
35. Randall, Colombia and the United States, 199. See also Bradley Coleman, Colombia and the United States: The Making of an Inter-American Alliance, 1939-1960 (Kent, OH: The Kent State University Press), 2008.
36. Stueck, Korean War, 198.
37. Connell-Smith, United States and Latin America, 207.
38. Connell-Smith, United States and Latin America, 207; Edwin Lieuwen, Arms and Politics in Latin America, rev. ed. (New York: Frederick A. Praeger, 1961), 198–202.
39. LaFeber, America, Russia, and the Cold War, 136.
40. Stephen G. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America: The Foreign Policy of Anticommunism (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1988), 6.
41. Stephen G. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 1–5, 26; Mary S. McAulliffe, “Commentary: Eisenhower, the President,” Journal of American History 68 (December 1981): 625–32; Fred I. Greenstein, The Hidden-Hand Presidency: Eisenhower as Leader (New York: Basic Books, 1982); Mark T. Gilderhus, “An Emerging Synthesis? U.S.-Latin American Relations since 1945,” in Hogan, America in the World, 445–50. See also Stephen Kinzer, The Brothers: John Foster Dulles, Allen Dulles, and Their Secret World War (New York: Times Books), 2013.
42. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 26–29; H. W. Brands, Jr., “Milton Eisenhower and the Coming Revolution in Latin America,” in Brands, Cold Warriors: Eisenhower’s Generation and American Foreign Policy (New York: Columbia University Press, 1988); Milton S. Eisenhower, The Wine Is Bitter: The United States and Latin America (Garden City, NY: Doubleday, 1963), chap. 2.
43. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 29–30.
44. Robert J. McMahon, “Eisenhower and Third World Nationalism: A Critique of the Revisionists,” Political Science Review 101 (Fall 1986): 457.
45. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 30–36; Chester J. Pach, Jr., Arming the Free World: The Origins of the United States Military Assistance Program, 1945–1950 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1991), chap. 2; Lieuwen, Arms and Politics, chaps. 8–9.
46. Gilderhus, “An Emerging Synthesis?” 444; Bryce Wood, The Dismantling of the Good Neighbor Policy (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1985), chap. 9; Richard H. Immerman, The CIA in Guatemala: The Foreign Policy of Intervention (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1982); Piero Gleijeses, Shattered Hope: The Guatemalan Revolution and the United States, 1944–1954 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1991).
47. Kenneth J. Grieb, Guatemalan Caudillo: The Regime of Jorge Ubico, Guatemala, 1931–1944 (Athens: Ohio University Press, 1979), 18, 21.
48. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 43–47.
49. Smith, Last Years, 75–78.
50. Stephen E. Ambrose and Richard H. Immerman, Ike’s Spies: Eisenhower and the Espionage Establishment (Garden City, NY: Doubleday, 1981); John Prados, Presidents’ Secret Wars: CIA and Pentagon Covert Operations since World War II (New York: William Morrow, 1986); Rhodri Jeffreys-Jones, The CIA and American Democracy (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1989); Charles D. Ameringer, U.S. Foreign Intelligence: The Secret Side of American History (Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath, 1990).
51. Smith, Last Years, 70, 78; Wood, Dismantling of the Good Neighbor Policy; Immerman, CIA in Guatemala; Gleijeses, Shattered Hope.
52. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 49–56.
53. Smith, Last Years, 82–86; Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 56.
54. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 64; Burton I. Kaufman, Trade and Aid: Eisenhower’s Foreign Economic Policy, 1953–1961 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982).
55. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 64–75.
56. Victor Bulmer-Thomas, The Economic History of Latin America since Independence (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994), chaps. 8–9.
57. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 75–77. For consideration of an anomaly, see Kenneth Lehman, “Revolutions and Attributions: Making Sense of Eisenhower Administration Policies in Bolivia and Guatemala,” Diplomatic History 21 (Spring 1997): 185–213.
58. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 86, 89–90, 92, 102, chap. 6; Richard M. Nixon, Six Crises (Garden City, NY: Doubleday, 1962), chap. 4.
59. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 114.
60. Tad Szulc, Twilight of the Tyrants (New York: W. W. Holt, 1959); Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 107.
61. Rabe, Eisenhower and Latin America, 96–97, 110–14.
The twenty images that follow reflect both a long, sometimes contentious U.S.–Latin American relationship and the cultural uniqueness of the region. Most of the images were made recently by David LaFevor.