3.1 General Principles
With a scope seven times that of Fyodor Dostoyevsky’s War and Peace, the US tax code should leave nothing to chance. However, as shown by Sull and Eisenhardt (2015), authors of Simple Rules: How to Thrive in a Complex World, when 45 tax professionals took up the task of calculating one fictional family’s tax bill, they came up with 45 different estimates, with differences ranging in the tens of thousands of dollars. No wonder that “to navigate this (tax) labyrinth, U.S. citizens employ 1.2 million [tax professionals], more than all the police and firefighters in the country combined” (Sull and Eisenhardt 2015, p. 23). The example reveals how complexity can spiral out of control; in our context, it highlights William Baumol’s (1990) fundamental insight that society’s rules of the game give rise to a “social structure of payoffs” determining whether individuals devote their time and energy to productive, unproductive, or destructive purposes. The European situation regarding corporate and personal income taxation appears to be comparable in that respect (PwC 2019). Complex rules, especially in an area of such immense importance for entrepreneurial venturing as taxes, will likely limit the scope of productive entrepreneurial activity and the workings of collaborative innovation blocs.
Any analysis of the effects of taxes on entrepreneurship is further complicated by the fact that no specific tax on income from entrepreneurial efforts exists in practice in the USA, Europe, or anywhere else. Governments tax entrepreneurial value creation in several ways, notably as labor income, business income, current capital income (dividends and interest), or capital gains. The complex interactions among these taxes shape incentives. To disentangle these effects, we begin by focusing on the three main theoretical ways in which the tax system affects entrepreneurial activity (Henrekson and Sanandaji 2016).
First, an absolute effect influences the supply of potential entrepreneurs and the effort they exert in the economy, as an increase in the taxation of entrepreneurial incomes lowers their (expected) after-tax reward, adversely affecting entry, growth, and liquidity. Second, there is a relative effect influencing the relative returns for different activities; for example, a tax system favoring certain forms of savings and investments over others can have considerable indirect consequences for entrepreneurship. Likewise, a higher relative tax on formal employment may encourage income shifting and push more people into self-employment; whether it is the “right” people and whether they are choosing self-employment for the right reasons are different matters altogether. Lastly, the tax system (and regulation in general) can be so opaque and complex that it puts potential productive entrepreneurs at a disadvantage relative to individuals able and willing to game the system to their advantage. As such, the complexity effect benefits rent seekers, lobbyists, and tax arbitrageurs to the disadvantage of new entrants and productive ventures.
Bearing these effects in mind, we choose moderation as a first guiding principle: tax rates should be low to promote an entrepreneurial society. Perhaps more important still is to espouse the second principle of neutrality and aim for as small a bias as possible with regard to taxes across different owner categories, sources of finance, and economic activities (Elert et al. 2017). Finally, adherence to the principle of transparency is vital to make the tax system less opaque and exception-ridden.
Tax systems tend to grow increasingly complex and opaque over time because politicians, often prompted by vocal interest groups in society, continually tinker with the system at the margins. This corrosion highlights the need for an occasional overhaul of the tax code to do away with the exceptions and loopholes typically introduced to fix imbalances caused by changes elsewhere in the tax code. Because such a tax code reform requires a strong political mandate and momentum, the optimal moment of implementation is hard to predict; but when an opportunity presents itself, policymakers should embrace it.
The EU’s tax competencies are quite limited, meaning that most of the proposals presented below are directed to member states individually. That said, the EU can play a role by “nudging” national governments in the right direction and has several policy instruments at its disposal to do so. Such instruments include recommendations, policy statements developed by the Council, and nonbinding agreements between member states, which could be coupled with regular assessments, peer pressure, and the exchange of best practices between member states. The EU is entitled to take such supporting and coordinating actions whenever tax reforms touch upon the proper functioning of the internal market. This is arguably the case for taxes with a bearing on the efficient allocation of capital in the EU, such as corporate income taxation, dividend and capital gains taxation, and the fiscal treatment of debt, equity, and stock options (Suse and Hachez 2017).
3.2 Proposals
Given the complexities inherent in the relationship between taxes and entrepreneurship, we present reform proposals for the major tax categories in EU member states one at a time: labor, corporate, dividend, and capital gains, wealth, and stock options taxation. These proposals should primarily be considered at the member state level, either in isolation or, preferably, as part of a comprehensive tax reform.
3.2.1 Labor Taxation
While some entrepreneurs (such as owner-managers in incorporated businesses) are employees in their own companies, they seldom pay themselves a high salary, especially in early phases when liquidity tends to be constrained. Nevertheless, the emphasis on key personnel in the collaborative innovation bloc underscores the central role of labor taxation for successful entrepreneurial venturing. EU member states differ substantially in this respect.
Top marginal tax rate on labor income, and marginal rate of income tax plus employee and employer contributions less cash benefits (tax wedge), 2017
Tax wedges | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Country | Top marginal tax rate on labor income | Single no child, 100% AW | Single, no child, 167% AW | Married, 2 children, 100 and 67% AW |
Austria | 48.0 | 59.7 | 42.2 | 59.7 |
Belgium | 46.0 | 66.4 | 68.5 | 65.6 |
Czech Rep. | 20.1 | 48.6 | 48.6 | 48.6 |
Denmark | 55.8 | 42.0 | 55.8 | 42.0 |
Estonia | 19.7 | 41.2 | 41.2 | 41.2 |
Finland | 49.0 | 55.6 | 58.3 | 56.4 |
France | 53.9 | 58.5 | 59.9 | 60.4 |
Germany | 47.5 | 60.4 | 44.3 | 57.9 |
Greece | 55.0 | 49.1 | 61.6 | 49.1 |
Hungary | 15.0 | 46.2 | 49.0 | 46.2 |
Ireland | 48.0 | 54.0 | 55.8 | 35.9 |
Italy | 42.3 | 54.7 | 63.3 | 55.3 |
Luxembourg | 41.4 | 55.5 | 55.5 | 52.1 |
Netherlands | 49.7 | 51.6 | 52.7 | 51.6 |
Poland | 22.1 | 37.0 | 37.2 | 37.0 |
Portugal | 50.0 | 51.1 | 60.8 | 51.1 |
Slovakia | 21.7 | 46.4 | 46.5 | 46.4 |
Slovenia | 39.0 | 51.0 | 60.4 | 43.6 |
Spain | 43.5 | 48.3 | 37.0 | 48.3 |
Sweden | 60.1 | 48.3 | 67.3 | 48.4 |
UK | 45.0 | 40.2 | 49.0 | 40.3 |
USA | 46.3 | 43.6 | 43.6 | 34.3 |
To offset the negative impacts of high marginal and average labor taxation on labor supply, policymakers have tied many of the valuable transfers and welfare state services that these taxes finance (e.g., child care and pension rights) to employment. Moreover, taxation and social security have often been individualized to stimulate female labor participation (Lindbeck 1982). Such individualized conditionality explains why a country such as Sweden has the EU’s highest employment rate despite high marginal and average taxes on labor. However, if systems are poorly designed, they push people away from small, risky, and innovative ventures into secure, salaried employment in the public sector or in incumbent firms. More often than not, these high-taxation–high-conditionality systems violate our principles of moderation, neutrality, and transparency.
For Sweden, it has been argued that a reform to lower the marginal tax in the top bracket would probably more than finance itself (Sørensen 2010; Holmlund and Söderström 2011). The situation is different in the new eastern member states: despite low labor income tax rates, they exhibit little improvement-driven opportunity entrepreneurship and couple low employment with large underground economies. These circumstances suggest that factors other than high labor taxes are binding constraints for this cluster of countries and that lowering such taxes more would merely result in a harmful loss of tax income and the deterioration of public sector effectiveness. In contrast, labor taxation seems to be a clear impediment to venture creation and growth in the Mediterranean countries, as well as in Belgium and France. There, high taxes and the employment-related obligations of employers penalize both the employment of people and attempts to realize growth. Reforms in these countries should aim to combine lower labor taxes with more universal access to public services and social security, such as childcare and pension rights. We return to these issues when discussing the organization of labor markets and social security systems in Chap. 5.
Proposal 5: Reduce high tax burdens on labor instead of making subsidies, pension rights, and social benefits more conditional on employment status.
The proposal would ensure tax neutrality between different types of labor market engagement, reducing the disproportionately high penalty small employers face when hiring workers. Moreover, the proposal serves the principle of transparency by reducing the roundabout method of taxing labor income to finance transfers and to provide subsidized services to those that paid the tax.
3.2.2 Corporate Taxation
Corporate taxation has significant ramifications for the interplay between entrepreneurs and financiers in the collaborative innovation bloc; specifically, a high tax rate on business profits discourages equity financing and encourages debt financing if interest payments are tax-deductible (Desai et al. 2003; Huizinga et al. 2008). Because debt financing is less costly and more readily available to larger firms, high corporate tax rates coupled with tax-deductible interest payments put smaller firms and potential entrepreneurs at a disadvantage (Davis and Henrekson 1999) while also reducing the retained earnings that can be used to expand ventures after start-up. Consequently, taxing profits can be expected to affect growth negatively, especially in small firms (Michaelas et al. 1999).
Proposal 6: Eliminate discrepancies between statutory and effective corporate income tax rates.
It is imperative that these discrepancies be addressed, as it becomes more difficult to realize the behavioral effects that policymakers envision if economic actors can obtain an effective tax rate lower than the statutory one (Chetty et al. 2009). Moreover, all firms should be treated equally under corporate income tax law.
There is, however, one (transparent but decidedly non-neutral) exception to the equal treatment rule that we would consider appropriate: that start-ups be allowed to retain their profits for reinvestment. The fact that new firms create useful knowledge about new technologies and business models (even if they ultimately fail) justifies this departure from the neutrality principle. This does not mean that personal incomes earned from start-ups should be tax exempt, as this could trigger unproductive tax arbitrage and promote solo self-employment (Liebregts 2016). This reform would make it easier and more attractive to make and reinvest profits while simultaneously creating a tough selection environment for firms without creating a need to develop (transparent, democratic, and accountable) criteria for public support. In addition, this supports new ventures without siphoning off resources from successful firms and avoids the risk that direct government support is channeled to the wrong firms. The latter risk is far from negligible; it could induce entrepreneurs to spend less time and effort on catering to consumer demands, and more on developing expertise in getting such public support (Gustafsson et al. 2018). In the extreme case, entrepreneurial profits could be made fully tax exempt. However, such a policy would only be effective when statutory corporate tax rates are also effective corporate tax rates, as proposed above.
Proposal 7: Grant full corporate income tax exemption to genuinely new, innovative start-ups through their 3rd year, with the long-term goal of abolishing corporate income taxation altogether.
Clearly, the short-term goal of this proposal violates one of the principles we hold dear: neutrality. Moreover, it may give rise to undesirable tax-induced arrangements and does not distinguish between innovation-based new ventures producing knowledge spillovers and low-tech replicative ventures. However, because it is difficult for bureaucrats to distinguish deserving from non-deserving ventures, it is probably best to refrain from fine-tuning this further. Regardless, start-ups rarely make big profits in their first years, meaning that the proposal will not be costly in terms of foregone tax revenue. Fulfilling its long-term goal could, furthermore, make it a vital step towards a tax system in line with the desired principles of transparency, neutrality, and moderation.
3.2.3 Taxation of Dividends and Capital Gains
The returns to entrepreneurship mainly accrue to investors and entrepreneurs in the form of dividends and capital gains on their firm ownership stake. A high dividend tax rate encourages entrepreneurs to rely on retained earnings to finance expansion but can also trap capital in incumbent firms, thereby obstructing the flow of capital to the most promising projects in a collaborative innovation bloc (Chetty and Saez 2005). This imbalance is probably part of the reason why owners receive most of their economic return from successful entrepreneurship in the form of increased share values. Consequently, the taxation of capital gains on stock holdings typically has a substantial effect on the financial incentives of potential high-impact entrepreneurs and their (equity) financiers (Cumming 2005; Da Rin et al. 2006).
The standard dividend and capital gains tax rates (short-term/long-term) in EU member countries and the USA, 2018
Country | Dividends | Capital gains | Country | Dividends | Capital gains |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Austria | 27.5 | 27.5 | Latvia | 0.0 | 20.0 |
Belgium | 30.0 | 0.0 | Lithuania | 15.0 | 15.0 |
Bulgaria | 5.0 | 41.0 | Luxembourg | 21.0 | 42.0 |
Croatia | 12.0 | 12.0 | Malta | 0.0 | 35.0 |
Cyprus | 17.0 | 0.0 | Netherlands | 25.0 | n/aa |
Czech Republic | 15.0 | 15/0 | Poland | 19.0 | 19.0 |
Denmark | 42.0 | 42.0 | Portugal | 28.0 | 28.0 |
Estonia | 0.0 | 21.0 | Romania | 5.0 | 10.0 |
Finland | 28.9 | 34.0 | Slovakia | 7.0 | 25/0 |
France | 30.0 | 30.0 | Slovenia | 25.0 | 25/0 |
Germany | 26.4 | 26.4/0 | Spain | 23.0 | 23.0 |
Greece | 15.0 | 15.0 | Sweden | 30.0 | 30.0 |
Hungary | 15.0 | 15.0 | UK | 38.1 | 28.0 |
Ireland | 51.0 | 33.0 | USA | 29.2 | 39.6/20 |
Italy | 26.0 | 26.0 |
Proposal 8: Countries should aim for low dividend and capital gains tax rates with few exceptions and few (opaque) concessionary schemes.
Dividend taxation also creates an undesirable differential in the risk-adjusted returns on debt and equity that possibly biases the supply of financial capital away from small, uncertain, experimental entrepreneurial venturing. We would, therefore, propose dividend taxation be kept low and at a par with the fiscal treatment of interest income on debt to avoid such biases. A similar argument holds for capital gains taxation to the extent that retained profits drive capital gains. To promote a more entrepreneurial society, the tax system should not be biased against the most relevant sources of finance for entrepreneurial venturing.
3.2.4 Taxation of Private Wealth
Proposal 9: Harmonize and reduce taxes on private wealth, private wealth transfers, and inheritance if productively invested.
Because the incomes used to build up private wealth have typically already been taxed, some would argue that any form of private wealth taxation is double taxation (Boadway et al. 2010). A country may choose to tax the wealth of its citizens for equity reasons, but the fact that this gives rise to unproductive tax arbitrage (Harrington 2016; Zucman 2014, 2015; Montes 2018) is probably why most European countries have lowered wealth taxation. However, as shown in Table A.1 in the Appendix, countries such as France and Spain still tax wealth at steep rates even if the exempted amounts are sizable. The real effective tax rate on wealth income can become extremely high in the current low interest regime: For instance, a wealth tax of 2% is a real tax that is levied in addition to any tax on the nominal return of the asset. Invariably, this problem forces the government to introduce distortionary safety valves (e.g., Du Rietz and Henrekson 2015).
Equity considerations, while relevant, should take a backseat to ensuring that accumulated private wealth is mobilized and productively invested (Krippner 2005; Hudson and Bezemer 2012; Piketty et al. 2013; Bezemer 2014; Bezemer and Hudson 2016). The entrepreneurial society loses out when its wealthy families become rentier dynasties, i.e., passive portfolio investors in large incumbent firms and real estate. Preferably, their accumulated wealth should be used to create opportunities for the next generation of entrepreneurs (Acs and Phillips 2002; Acs 2006; Auerswald and Acs 2009). Acs and Phillips (2002) argue that in the USA, wealthy entrepreneurs perform this function in part through philanthropy. Historically, European nations have relied more on the taxation of accumulated wealth, wealth income, and inheritance, redistributing the proceeds through publicly funded investments in, e.g., education and health.
To ensure that Europe’s wealthy families reinvest their fortunes in promising ventures on their own accord, a preferential treatment of equity investments in young SMEs could be considered. Alternatively, leaving private wealth invested unproductively could carry a penalty (Shakow and Shuldiner 1999).3 Whichever route is chosen to mobilize more private wealth for entrepreneurial venturing, a strong case can be made for a harmonization of wealth taxation at the Union level. Appropriately implemented, such a measure would prevent a legislative race to the bottom and minimize the scope for unproductive tax evasion. Such considerations would benefit the current debate on European wealth taxation, which appears to be dominated by concerns of tax revenue and equity (Astarita 2014; Krenek and Schratzenstaller 2018).
Proposal 10: Harmonize inheritance taxes across member states and introduce a moderate flat tax rate and exempt the majority of inheritances from taxation.
Most Western European countries have reduced their inheritance taxation significantly since the 1960s. Interestingly, the tax is least popular among the lower income brackets. Following the work of Piketty (2015), however, the issue of preventing the accumulation of “dead” wealth has resurfaced in the policy debate (e.g., The Economist 2017). While there are strong arguments for taxing inheritances, the devil is, as always, in the details. The primary purpose of this tax should not be to raise revenue but to incentivize the productive investment of wealth. People should be discouraged from rolling over large fortunes into risk-free portfolios of government bonds, and the liquidation of productive ventures to avoid inheritance taxation would be especially damaging. A moderate and harmonized inheritance tax would broaden the tax base while limiting the incentives and opportunities for tax avoidance. Furthermore, in member states where family-owned businesses are engines of innovation and growth, policymakers should consider additional means to strengthen the entrepreneurial society, for example, by introducing exemptions for wealth that remains productively invested in family firms.
Reducing and simplifying the taxation of private wealth are the first steps towards freeing up more savings for productive investment in entrepreneurial ventures. Those steps are not enough, however, if the interests and skills of private wealth owners do not meet the entrepreneurial sector’s needs. Here, a well-developed financial sector, to which we return below, has an important role as a matchmaker and intermediary.
3.2.5 Tax Neutral Treatment of Equity and Debt
Innovative entrepreneurs have limited access to bank credit and tradable debt obligations. They may borrow from friends, family, and fools or through crowdlending, but these types of lending are often exposed to the same risks as equity and given in anticipation of the same return profiles (with no formal governance rights). The reason is that innovative start-ups face large disadvantages in attracting more formal forms of debt finance due to high uncertainty and the lack of a robust track record and readily collateralizable assets. Therefore, tax structures that favor debt over equity investments will, often unintentionally, bias the flow of financial resources away from innovative entrepreneurial venturing and impede the workings of the collaborative innovation bloc. Moreover, the tax-deductibility of interest payments has provided large firms with ample room for artificially shifting profits to low or zero-tax locations (OECD 2017).
Currently, national tax systems in Europe favor debt finance. Debt becomes (too) cheap relative to equity because interest payments are deductible as operating costs, while dividends are subject to corporate income taxation before they can be paid out to shareholders. Moreover, strong legal creditor protection reduces risks for creditors that would otherwise justify a higher risk premium on debt finance. Together, these fiscal and institutional arrangements bias the supply of finance towards debt, and entrepreneurs are at a disadvantage when competing for debt relative to homeowners, large multinationals, and other actors. As such, debt finance channels society’s available savings into the reproduction and growth of the existing capital stock, and a case can be made that only equity type investments finance innovation and progress beyond the status quo (Polzin et al. 2018a).
Neutrality between debt and equity can be achieved in two principal ways: by reducing the tax advantages of debt finance or by giving similar advantages to equity (e.g., De Mooij and Devereux 2016). The EU’s efforts in this regard have mainly been to reduce interest deductibility. In 2016, the European Council (2016) adopted the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive (ATAD), which lays down rules against tax avoidance practices that directly affect the functioning of the internal market. Article 4 in the Directive stipulates a limit to interest deductions: net interest payments cannot exceed a certain percentage of company earnings, typically defined as 30% of earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBITDA), allowing for a minimum deductible amount independent of earnings. Table A.3 in the Appendix shows that almost all member states have instituted such rules, with most of them settling for a minimum deductible amount of EUR 3 million.
Unfortunately, the Council has prioritized its concern regarding tax base erosion over the need to even out the imbalance between debt and equity as sources of finance. It is unclear to what extent the EBITDA rules will be binding for incumbent firms, and if the rules are not binding, they will do nothing to reduce the difference in effective taxation of debt and equity.
Proposal 11: Initiate a balanced program aiming to achieve tax neutrality between debt and equity finance.
In an entrepreneurial society, it is (primarily) equity investments that enable innovative entrepreneurial venturing and thereby generate useful knowledge about the products, services, and business models that work or fail. This knowledge constitutes a positive externality, which may even justify the preferential tax treatment of equity investments over debt.4 At the very least, the long-term ambition should be to eliminate any fiscal advantages held by debt finance over equity.
3.2.6 Taxation of Stock Options
The fiscal treatment of stock options deserves special mention, harking back to the role played by key personnel in the collaborative innovation bloc. As a promise of a future ownership stake, employee stock options are used to encourage and reward individuals who supply key competencies to a young firm that is typically short on cash. However, their value—and effectiveness as an incentive mechanism—greatly depends on the option tax code, notably on whether employees can defer the tax liability until they sell the stocks (and whether they are taxed at a low capital gains tax rate at this point) (Gilson and Schizer 2003).
Proposal 12: Taxes on capital gains on stock options and the underlying stock in start-ups should be low and only be taxed when exercised and/or sold, i.e., when gains are realized.
In many EU countries, the lower taxation of gains on employee stock options in the start-up sector is necessary, both as a means to lure talented people away from traditional careers in incumbent firms and to channel institutional capital into the entrepreneurial sector, which should be mediated by a professional VC sector. A tax break that targets human capital in this segment would promote innovative entrepreneurship without the high fiscal cost of broad capital gains tax cuts (Henrekson and Sanandaji 2018c).
3.3 Summary
Taxation is essential to any government’s ability to finance essential public infrastructure and collective goods. Therefore, where we argue in favor of moderation, healthy government finances are assumed. Inevitably, this implies that countries in the Union will end up with different tax levels and rates. However, given the aggregate level of tax income required to ensure a long-term stable government budget, we maintain that moderate, neutral, and transparent taxation are key to boosting entrepreneurial venturing across Europe. Adhering to these three principles requires an ongoing effort to keep the tax system simple, clear, and effective in the face of interest groups lobbying for exemptions and exceptions. The alternative is less transparency, impaired neutrality, and increased complexity, which will distort behavior.
Summary of proposals regarding taxation, specifying the level in the governance hierarchy where the necessary decisions should be made
No. | Principle(s) | Policy area | Proposal | Policy levela |
---|---|---|---|---|
5 | Neutrality and transparency | Labor taxation | Reduce high tax burdens on labor instead of making subsidies, pension rights, and social benefits more conditional on employment status. | MS |
6 | Transparency | Corporate income taxation | Eliminate discrepancies between statutory and effective corporate income tax rates. | EU, MS |
7 | Moderation and transparency | Corporate income taxation | Grant full corporate income tax exemption to genuinely new, innovative start-ups through their third year, with the long-term goal of abolishing corporate income taxation altogether. | EU, MS |
8 | Moderation and transparency | Dividend and capital gains taxation | Countries should aim for low dividend and capital gains tax rates with few exceptions and few (opaque) concessionary schemes. | EU, MS |
9 | Moderation and neutrality | Wealth taxation | Harmonize and reduce taxes on private wealth, private wealth transfers, and inheritance if productively invested. | MS |
10 | Moderation and neutrality | Inheritance taxation | Harmonize inheritance taxes across member states and introduce a moderate flat tax rate and exempt the majority of inheritances from taxation. | EU, MS |
11 | Neutrality | Debt and equity taxation | Initiate a balanced program aiming to achieve tax neutrality between debt and equity finance. | EU, MS |
12 | Moderation | Stock options taxation | Taxes on capital gains on stock options and the underlying stock in start-ups should be low and only be taxed when exercised and/or sold, i.e., when gains are realized. | EU, MS |
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter's Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter's Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.