Labor Market Challenges
The best actor award at the 2015 Cannes Film Festival went to a Frenchman, Vincent Lindon. In La loi du marché (literally, “The law of the market,” titled The Measure of a Man in English), he plays a middle-aged factory worker, Thierry, who has been fired as part of a cost-cutting exercise. Thierry takes part in one retraining program after another and repeatedly meets with counselors at the unemployment office, all to no avail. Struggling with financial problems (his home loan, a disabled son), he takes a job as a guard in a supermarket. The film tells of a store manager who distrusts his employees, monitors them, and will fire them from one day to the next for minor mischief, and of Thierry’s struggle to preserve his dignity. This film depicts a deep malaise of French society—the lack of decent jobs so that many citizens are weakened or marginalized, and the sometimes very conflictual relations between employers and employees.
The film’s title seems to suggest a degree of fatalism—as if this grim reality were the direct consequence of the market economy; as if it were to be expected that an employee who loses his job at the age of fifty might no longer be able to find another one; as if it were to be taken for granted that retraining programs, whose phenomenal cost is paid indirectly by the employees themselves, will not lead to anything; as if we ought to accept that a large number of workers should move from one unrewarding short-term contract to another, filling the gaps with state-subsidized jobs and unemployment benefits; as if men and women who are still young, in good physical shape, and eager to work had to be declared unfit for work and sent prematurely into retirement, a retirement financed by taxes levied on those who are still working. Is this the law of the market or a choice made by society?
It is not only France that has labor market problems. The British movie I, Daniel Blake, paints a similar picture of its lead character’s seemingly inevitable downward spiral into unsatisfying jobs, dismal relations with supervisors, and inadequate welfare benefits. In the United States, many authors have documented the widespread use of short-term and zero-hours contracts, and the conflict over increases in minimum wages, leaving many people struggling to make ends meet. The details of how the labor market and the benefits system are organized differ greatly from country to country, as do their rates of unemployment: the US and UK have relatively low unemployment rates, whereas in France and other southern European countries, the jobless rate is high, especially among young people.
In this chapter, I will illustrate my points using the case of France and will therefore start by briefly reviewing the facts of its labor market. While the institutional details are specific to my own country, this chapter’s lessons extend to a number of others.
First, there are some whose labor market institutions are similar to the French ones—including, for example, judicial control over redundancies, the prevalence of long-term unemployment, dysfunctional human resource management incentives for firms, the pervasiveness of short-term contracts when new jobs are created, high unemployment among the young, the old, and the unskilled, and a high cost of unemployment in terms of the government budget deficit. Southern Europe (Spain, Portugal, Italy, and Greece) immediately comes to mind.
Second, even for countries with lower unemployment or more new job creation now, the combination of globalization, technological change, and migration brings to the fore political demands to protect workers through protectionism, anti-immigration laws, taxes on “robots,” and a range of labor market regulations to deal with redundancies and the “uberization” of society. The longstanding idea that workers are not “disposable commodities” is gaining new prominence in the employment policy debate, as the current technological revolution is likely to bring about an unprecedentedly rapid change in the nature of work in future.1 Indeed, concern about the impact of automation and artificial intelligence on work in the market economy is already clear. People’s fears about their work conditions and future prospects are already fueling populist movements. There is a sense that policy makers are not doing enough—and worse, that they don’t even know what they should do. Politicians are being asked to wave a magic wand to assuage these concerns about job instability, degrading conditions of work, and increasing inequality. Some politicians will promise the impossible. But you do not need to be living on one of the southern European countries to understand the implications of otherwise well-intentioned job protection policies, and why it is better to protect workers than to protect jobs.
This chapter shows that unemployment is in part a choice that French society has made, and explains why. The chapter shows why mass unemployment and a dual labor market are not inevitable, and proposes avenues for reform. I will focus on employment contracts as an emblematic reform, but it is important to note that reform of the employment contract is only one part of a broader reform of labor market institutions with other, equally dysfunctional aspects. These should also be reformed in order to return to full employment, which France has not experienced for more than forty years. I will discuss some of these other aspects at the end of the chapter. I will explain why these reforms are urgent; in short, although unemployment in France and other similar countries has been slowly worsening for many years, a perfect storm of circumstances has formed that could throw them into a far more serious employment crisis. Finally, I will link the problems in the French labor market to the universal question of how to shape policies that give people in market economies a good chance of stable jobs with decent pay and conditions, particularly when globalization and new technologies seem to be threatening many people’s future livelihoods.
THE LABOR MARKET IN FRANCE
Saying that France’s performance in matters of employment and well-being at work is less than brilliant is an understatement. A quick international comparison clearly shows its poor performance is closer to the troubled economies of southern Europe than northern Europe.
1. Unemployment is much higher in France than in Northern European countries (Germany, the Netherlands, the Scandinavian countries) or the developed English-speaking countries (US, UK, Canada, Australia);
2. It affects mainly people between fifteen and twenty-four and between fifty-five and sixty-four years old;
3. Unemployment penalizes those with little education or training and those who live in low-income urban areas;
4. Long-term unemployment, which is by far the most harmful, is high and has been steadily increasing since 2007;
5. The French experience a serious malaise at work resulting from a lack of job mobility, conflictual relationships in the workplace, and a feeling that their jobs are not secure;
6. As a result, French taxpayers have to spend heavily on employment policy.
How many unemployed people are there in France? Answering this question turns out to be devilishly difficult. The most inherently conservative estimate stems from the definition given by the International Labor Organization (ILO).2 It indicated 2.9 million unemployed during the third trimester of 2015, or an unemployment rate of about 10.6 percent. This was more than double the German level, for instance, and far higher than those of developed English-speaking countries or northern Europe. But this definition does not take into account almost 1.5 million unemployed persons who would like to work.3 Statistics from the French ministry of labor4 distinguish five types of jobseekers. The figure most commonly reported in the media is: “jobseekers expected to make active attempts to find work, but who are currently unemployed” (Category A). By this definition, there were 3,574,860 unemployed in metropolitan France in November 2015. Yet this Category A figure for unemployment also underestimates the total because it does not include the other categories of unemployed persons: those who are in training programs, doing internships, without a job but on sick leave or maternity leave, working on subsidized contracts or part time, etc.5 Including everyone in these categories, in November 2015 there were about 6,142,000 unemployed.
Definitional issues are common to all countries, and media attention normally focuses on one rather than another, although people are quick to notice when the government tries to manipulate the figures by moving certain unemployed claimants from one category to another. Another difficulty encountered in measuring unemployment concerns unlisted unemployed persons—those who have become discouraged by the deterioration of the labor market, ranging from young people who are continuing their studies or who take a job abroad because they do not find employment in France, to older people who would like to continue working but decide instead to take retirement. Faced by this complexity in measuring unemployment, economists sometimes prefer to look at employment rates or labor force participation rates, sometimes delivering a different picture; for example, in the United States, labor force participation remained low for a long period after the 2008 crisis even as the unemployment rate declined rapidly.6
WHO Is MOST AFFECTED BY UNEMPLOYMENT
Two age groups suffer particularly from high unemployment in France. Those aged between fifteen and twenty-four have difficulty finding work. Their unemployment rate is 24 percent. Their employment rate (28.6 percent) is far lower than the OECD average (39.6 percent) and the rates in northern Europe (46.8 percent for Germany and 62.3 percent for the Netherlands).7 The French labor market is thus relatively closed to new entrants, particularly young people looking for their first job. To be sure, all countries have higher youth unemployment rates than among the rest of the population. Businesses are less eager to hire employees without prior experience, and especially to pay the cost of on-the-job training for young employees who, once they have completed their training or gained enough experience, may leave the company. However, young French people pay a harsh penalty compared with northern Europe or the English-speaking countries.
A consequence of this is growing intergenerational inequality. Not only are the young unemployed at a far higher rate than older people, but they also have trouble finding housing.8 Areas with vibrant economies, creating jobs, often also have the tightest housing markets. In fact, public policies limiting new building have worsened housing shortages, while policies unfavorable to landlords have limited the supply of rental housing, increased rents, and led to demands for large security deposits. Finally, because their employment is often unstable, many young people cannot obtain a mortgage.
People between fifty-five and sixty-four years old often take early retirement, whether willingly or unwillingly—earlier in France than in any other European country. Their employment rate (45.6 percent) is also far below the OECD average and in particular the rates in northern Europe (the employment rate in this age group in Sweden exceeds 70 percent). Those over fifty who are still active in the labor market are also the main victims of long-term unemployment; 56 percent of unemployed people aged fifty and over fall into this category. More generally, in 2016 just over 4 percent of those still wanting to work had been unemployed for more than a year, almost twice the level in northern European countries. It is commonly acknowledged that long-term unemployment is much more harmful to the individual than a short spell of unemployment. It leads to a loss of vocational qualifications, social isolation, and a stigma when trying to get back into the labor market. The fact that long-term unemployment is particularly high in France is an additional cause of concern.
Younger and older people experience higher unemployment rates than prime-age workers in many countries, but the degree to which they are penalized is higher in France than in many others.
AN EXPENSIVE EMPLOYMENT POLICY THAT PRODUCES DISAPPOINTING RESULTS
Every government spends money on its employment policies. The goals are to train workers, to help the most vulnerable, and to protect those who have had the bad luck to find themselves in a sector undergoing technological and economic change. Nevertheless, the amount France spends on its employment policy far exceeds international norms. This is, obviously, money that is not available for education, healthcare, and other public services, or alternatively (depending on one’s point of view), money that weighs down public finances and increases the burden of government debt repayments. Unemployment is expensive not only for workers, but also for society in general.
What the notion of public employment policy means is a matter of debate. It may include unemployment insurance (thirty-one billion euros in 2014), assistance with coping with economic changes, and funds allocated for the vocational retraining of unemployed workers. It can also cover the cost of public employment services, subsidized jobs (in the non-profit sector, contracts combining on-the-job and classroom training, jobs in urban development zones), and what are known as general measures. These measures can encompass the reduction of employer taxes on low salaries, tax credits to encourage competitiveness and employment, and—specific to France—funds allocated to help offset the costs of capping the work week at thirty-five hours.9 The total budgeted amount has been steadily increasing since 1993. In 2012, France was spending 1.41 percent of its GDP on “passive” policies (unemployment insurance) and 0.87 percent on “active” policies (training for unemployed workers, funding the relevant agencies, subsidized jobs, etc.).10 If we add to this various fiscal incentives, the total reaches about 3.5 or 4 percent of GDP.11
THE RESORT TO QUICK FIXES
To reduce unemployment, successive governments in France (and in other southern European countries) have encouraged fixed-term contracts and subsidized jobs.
Subsidized jobs. These constitute, on the whole, a poor use of public funds, particularly for subsidized jobs in the noncommercial sector.12 Rather than encouraging employers to use employees because it is cheap to do so, the money could be used instead to reduce social security contributions and thus incentivize companies to create the stable jobs they and their employees really need. Indeed, France has the highest social security contributions among OECD countries.13
Of course, I’m exaggerating a little here. Subsidizing jobs for unskilled young people may be justified on the basis of a “market failure”: the company provides, at a loss, the young employee with human capital that it will gain no benefit from if the employee quits to get a higher salary elsewhere. But on the whole, the statistics show that the probability of finding a job with a permanent contract after holding a subsidized position is low, and that the beneficiaries of subsidized jobs in the noncommercial sector have less chance of being employed two years later. Thus the hypothesis that a subsidized job is a springboard to a stable job remains to be proven.
Insecure jobs. The great majority of newly created jobs in France, 85 percent in 2013, now have fixed-term (or temporary) contracts, and this ratio is steadily rising (it was 75 percent in 1999). There has also been a big increase in ultra-short-term contracts (the employee being registered as a jobseeker between two contracts with the same employer), which are not very satisfactory for the employee and very expensive for unemployment insurance.14 Today, more than one hire out of two on a fixed-term contract is a rehire in the same company.
In reality, employment on limited-term contracts is not good for either the employee or the employer. For the former, the contract offers little protection. Since in theory (although this is frequently ignored in practice) prolonging or renewing a limited-term contract legally transforms it into a permanent contract, regulation gives the employer a very strong incentive not to do so, even if the employee’s performance is satisfactory.15 This is precisely the opposite of what regulation is intended to achieve, in terms of employee protection. In fact, within Europe, France is the country where the transition from a temporary contract to a stable contract occurs the least frequently.16 Which means that elsewhere in Europe, a person hired on the basis of a temporary contract has a much greater chance of seeing this temporary contract transformed into a permanent job. The fact that companies resort extensively to fixed-term contracts, which neither they nor their employees like, is very revealing of the implicit cost imposed on French society by current laws regarding permanent contracts.
Nonetheless, successive French governments, knowing businesses’ reluctance to use permanent contracts, have not dared alter fixed-term employment contracts. The latter serve as a safety valve for the excessively rigid rules concerning permanent contracts; it makes it possible to safeguard a minimum number of jobs and thus prevents an exorbitant rise in the unemployment figures. The polarization of terms of employment between an ultraflexible fixed-term contract and an ultrarigid permanent contract divides the labor market between those who spend more and more time trying to find a real job, and those who have been hired for an unlimited period and whose jobs are protected. In other words, this polarization is a dirty trick played on employees in general, and especially on the young.17
Even so, political debate is focused on dismissals of employees who have permanent contracts. Such dismissals represent only a small fraction of terminations (4.4 percent) and are supervised by the courts, with additional governmental pressure if the subject gets media coverage. On the other hand, the debate ignores almost completely the two principal causes of turnover in the labor market: resignations, which are few in number (9 percent of terminations) and decreasing, and above all terminations at the end of a fixed-term contract, which are far more numerous (77 percent) and are steadily increasing. (The rest consists of terminations by mutual agreement,18 those at the end of probationary periods, and retirements.)
The French exceptionalism in terms of the figures does not mean that other countries lack labor market rigidities whose effects can be counterproductive. For example, Spain has a high rate of unemployment among young people for similar reasons. Countries that have more flexible labor market institutions may still encounter difficulties in delivering good jobs, especially to the young. In the UK and US, employers have increasingly been creating insecure work in the form of zero-hours contracts, while self-employment and agency work has also become more prevalent, prompting much debate about whether policies need to change. While the US experiences a low unemployment rate, one in six working-age men without a college degree is not part of the workforce.19
MALAISE IN THE WORKPLACE
For employees, unemployment and precarious employment are the tip of the iceberg. The hidden part is multiform …
Insufficient mobility and imperfect matching of employees to jobs. It is natural that employees move from one company to another. They may wish to take on new professional challenges and acquire knowledge while exploring new horizons. They may also want to leave coworkers or superiors with whom they have difficult relationships. Conversely, in a changing economy, companies may wish to reorient their activities to adapt, and seek to hire employees with skills different from those they hired earlier. The perception in France that a job with a permanent contract is a (very relative) privilege, to be clung to for fear of not finding an equivalent position, facilitates neither mobility nor the matching of employees to jobs, which entails a cost for both employees and companies.
Conflictual relationships. Relations between employers and employees are not harmonious in France. France ranks 129th out of 139 countries in terms of people’s perception of relationships at work.20 We can only guess at the causes of this unfortunate French peculiarity, which contributes to employee burnout. Perhaps the absence of mobility just mentioned plays a role. An employee whose relationship with coworkers or superiors has grown tense will normally change jobs in a fluid labor market, but in France he or she does not have that option and will remain, despite the conflict. It is not impossible, either, that some less than scrupulous employers may deliberately worsen an employee’s work environment in order to give him or her an incentive to accept a mutually agreed-upon termination and to leave the company; this allows the employer to avoid a hearing before a labor tribunal.
The French report suffering from considerable stress at work. Studies conducted on the basis of international data21 demonstrate a positive correlation between legislation protecting jobs and stress at work. This correlation is hardly surprising. As we have seen, rigidity in jobs and the scarcity of jobs damage relationships at work in several ways: employees unsatisfied with their jobs hold on to them nonetheless, and unscrupulous bosses can easily play on the fear of unemployment to intimidate employees.
A strong sense of job insecurity. Job insecurity is obviously felt by workers with fixed-term contracts, whose jobs are by definition precarious. More surprisingly, workers with permanent contracts also feel insecure, even though they benefit from what are in practice the world’s most protective labor laws.22 This observation is not as paradoxical as it seems, insofar as a worker with a “permanent” contract knows that if he is fired or his firm goes bankrupt and he becomes unemployed, his chances of finding an equivalent job are limited. This leads to a feeling of pessimism that pervades the whole of French society and paralyzes it, handicapping its ability to adapt and innovate. While the French example is extreme, it illustrates the degree to which employment laws may have unintended consequences.
THE NEED FOR REFORM
One argument often advanced against the necessity of reforming labor institutions in France is that unemployment reflects a weak demand for companies’ products, and that a macroeconomic reflation would reduce unemployment. There is no doubt that France, like all European countries, is suffering from an uncertain outlook and is subject to the aftereffects of the financial and European crises.23 Favorable prospects and a well-filled order book would obviously have very positive effects on employment. But the macroeconomic argument is not relevant, for several reasons.
The most obvious of these reasons is that unemployment is structural, not only cyclical. It has not fallen below 7 percent in France for thirty years, despite an employment policy that is very costly, measures paying workers to retire several years early, and encouragement to use fixed-term contracts. It is no accident that unemployment in other countries of southern Europe, whose labor market institutions have similar origins to that of their French counterparts, is far higher than in northern Europe or the English-speaking countries. Contrast the UK, where the unemployment rate peaked at 8.5 percent after the financial crisis but has declined to 4.7 percent in 2017 despite the UK government’s budget austerity measures. Secondly, although the appropriate level for the budget deficit in a period of recession can be debated,24 we have been experiencing a Keynesian reflation resulting from the decrease in the value of the euro, lower interest rates, and a fall in the price of oil; unemployment should therefore be decreasing rather than increasing. Thirdly, we should wonder why companies’ order books are not very full. This brings us back in part to the question of the competitiveness of French businesses (which includes factors other than hourly pay, such as how easy it is to match employees to the right jobs, social security contributions, or management styles). Finally, a reflation by means of a budget deficit involves less risk when public finances are sound than when they are already in bad shape (as a result of forty years of budget laxity).
AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LABOR CONTRACTS25
MAKING EMPLOYERS ACCOUNTABLE FOR THE COSTS OF DISMISSALS
Work contracts and rules about redundancies and layoffs have to reconcile two objectives. Employees are not responsible for and have no control over technological change or demand shocks faced by their employers; they must therefore be insured against the risk that their jobs might become obsolete or simply unprofitable. For its part, the company will insist on flexibility in its management of human resources as it copes with these supply and demand shocks. Without this, it will be reluctant to create jobs in the first place, because it will incur large losses in the event that these jobs are not very productive. Two diametrically opposed points of view? Not necessarily. But to reconcile these two aims, the employee, not the job, has to be protected.
The employer knows whether a job is profitable for the firm—profitability properly conceived, of course, because an employer can cope with temporary losses on a workstation or a production unit due to a temporary decrease in demand, and yet still profit in the long run by retaining the job. The employer has the information needed to manage human resources. But we also have to ask what impact his choice between keeping the employee or letting him go might have on the company’s stakeholders.
In this case, there are at least two stakeholders: The first is the employee concerned, who suffers a financial cost from the loss of earnings as well as a psychological cost (for example, the loss of the social connections provided by the job, or family tensions). The externality created by dismissal is the rationale for two forms of compensation for the employee: the company grants severance pay, and government unemployment insurance provides replacement income and possibly also free training. The second set of stakeholders, often forgotten in this debate, includes those who pay for the provision of unemployment insurance, benefits, unemployed workers’ retraining expenditures, employment agency costs, etc. This second set of stakeholders is largely comprised of other firms, which finance these expenditures through their payroll taxes (social security contributions), and, if the social security system is in deficit, the taxpayer.
The principle of accountability that is the keystone of our economic system in other domains would prescribe that when a company fires an employee, it should “internalize” the external cost to society: both the cost to the employee and the cost to the social system. If it does not, it will have a tendency to dismiss employees too often (here I deliberately ignore regulatory constraints on dismissal, which I will discuss in detail later on). In order for the firm to internalize the cost to the welfare system, it must pay a penalty for dismissing workers, with the money going to the social security system or government budget and not to the employee.
It should be noted that this penalty need not be an additional tax burden on businesses, but might rather take the form of a system whereby the penalty could be earmarked to reduce social security contributions paid by employers who keep their workers on: the penalty is then fiscally neutral for business as a whole. However, although today everyone finds it reasonable that the polluter should pay in environmental matters,26 the idea that companies who fire employees should pay a penalty for doing so is not part of our economic software. Let us discuss in greater detail this unfamiliar “dismisser pays” principle.
A first question regarding this principle is how to calculate the cost of dismissals for the unemployment insurance fund. Firing a thirty-year-old software engineer in Paris who will find a job the next day costs nothing; but firing a fifty year old with few skills in a depressed job market is quite another matter. How then should we calculate the cost of the dismissal?
A clever way of calculating the penalty for dismissal consists of looking at how much the fired employee cost the unemployment insurance fund after he or she has been dismissed. This approach goes back to FDR’s United States, which set up a system on this principle that is still in operation, called “experience rating.”27 This has a twofold advantage: that of applying a higher penalty for dismissing employees who will have a harder time finding a job, and that of giving the company an incentive to invest in on-the-job training, thus enriching the human capital of its employees, and so limiting the length of time that they will be out of work in the event that they are dismissed. Similarly, it provides an incentive for management and labor in the same sector to improve the quality of ongoing vocational training, because they will be sensitized to the typical length of time people are unemployed.
We will see later that the reward-penalty system has other advantages, such as eliminating collusion between employers and employees at the expense of the social welfare system, and an improved allocation of activity among sectors of the economy.
DISCUSSION
The principle that the employer who dismisses an employee pays the associated social cost provides a general outline of how to achieve the desired accountability. It is, however, too simplistic; a few adjustments to the basic principle may be needed.28
Progressive rights. Although fixed-term contracts are undesirable and should be abolished, enterprises do need short-term employment for temporary tasks or seasonal activities. A single labor contract system with progressive rights for the employee is compatible with this need for short-term jobs.
Evasion mechanisms. As in the case of environmental damage, there is a danger that companies will evade regulation by subcontracting the work that is most unpredictable and thus most at risk of being terminated. By resorting to subcontractors who have no real capital and will be incapable of paying any penalty when their order book vanishes, they thus escape liability in the same way environmental cleanups can be dodged by transferring hazardous activities to subcontractors that are really empty shells. But, as in the case of environmental taxation, we can imagine ways to prevent these evasions: for example, demanding bank guarantees or tracing legal responsibility back to the parent company or the contractor (extended liability).
Selection effects. A reward-penalty system can lead enterprises to be cautious about hiring unreliable employees who are very likely not to satisfy the company’s requirements. This is obviously already the case today for permanent contracts, and more generally it will always be the case in any system in which the enterprise faces a cost for firing employees. However, it is possible to envisage the use of subsidies for hiring persons who are particularly disadvantaged on the labor market, or reducing somewhat the intensity of the reward-penalty system for such employees.
PERVERSE INSTITUTIONAL INCENTIVES
A TWOFOLD INCENTIVE TO COMMIT CRIME …
In France, a company firing its employees gives them severance pay, but it does not pay the cost of the dismissal to the unemployment insurance system, which may well be higher.29 On the other hand, a company retaining employees pays social security contributions, which include premiums for unemployment insurance. Companies that keep their employees on thus pay for the companies that fire them. This is upside down. By making companies that do not fire their employees pay the costs of dismissals incurred by the unemployment insurance system, the current system encourages dismissals in two ways.
… A MISSION IMPOSSIBLE ENTRUSTED TO THE JUDGE
Perhaps understanding that they were creating incentives to dismiss employees by making firms who do not lay off their workers pay (rather than those doing the firing), French legislators sought to compensate by regulating dismissals. This gave the courts the power to adjudicate on dismissals. However, whatever their competence and integrity, judges do not have the information that would make them better able than CEOs to decide the legitimacy of dismissals made on economic grounds. Consequently, the outcome of legal procedures involving such dismissals is completely arbitrary and unpredictable. Our institutions have entrusted the labor courts with a mission impossible.
THE HIDDEN COSTS OF FRENCH DISMISSAL PROCEDURES
If it gets to litigation, dismissal procedures30 result in major costs for the company far in excess of the payoffs to the employees who have been fired. The procedures are very lengthy (although they have been getting a little shorter lately). Suits relating to dismissals can be brought by the dismissed employee for up to two years.31 After the case is submitted to a court, a decision takes on average 13.6 months in the first instance and 35 months in the event of an appeal (which occurs in two-thirds of the cases). Not to mention that in a few cases there remains the risk of reinstatement—with payment of the interim salary.
The employer has to prove that there was a “real and serious cause” for the dismissal. In France, in contrast to many countries, the redundancy of a position, employee performance, or more generally the desire to cut costs are not considered legitimate reasons. A dismissal on economic grounds can only be justified if there are serious financial problems that put the company’s survival in danger, so a company that is otherwise healthy cannot stop an activity for which it no longer has a sustainable order book.32 Unsurprisingly, the cost to the company also includes the time its managers devote to dealing with the case (which takes them away from tasks involving the company’s future).
As for the employee, the process is costly, as well as unfair: those who are vulnerable and not very familiar with the complexity of the French system may be discouraged and may play the game less well than insiders33 who know how the institutions operate. Furthermore, there is also a great uncertainty as to the final decision and important disparities between labor tribunals.34
These inefficiencies would to a large extent disappear with the introduction of a reward-penalty system that would penalize companies for each dismissal in exchange for a reduction in their unemployment insurance contributions and less burdensome administrative and judicial procedures for dismissal. Companies could in fact be granted more flexibility in exchange for accepting this accountability. The principle of dismissal on grounds of economic redundancy would then be accepted, as it is in the US, northern Europe, and many other countries. This would balance the interests of employees, whose sense of identity and social connection depends on their work, and those of their employers, who want to be able to adapt their human resource management to economic and technological imperatives. On average, employees would not lose job security, because those currently on fixed-term contracts would then have a more stable job, and those on permanent contracts who lost their job would have a better chance of finding a new one. A penalty based on how long the laid-off workers stay unemployed would also encourage companies to invest in the human capital of their employees, so that when redundancies are necessary, they would remain unemployed for as short a time as possible.
Finally, the courts should not be taken completely out of the picture. For example, no matter what the system, one must be able to appeal to a judge in the event of unfair dismissal, say of a pregnant woman or of an annoying trade unionist. More generally, the courts must be able to intervene if an economic rationale for redundancies is used as cover for more personal, unacceptable motives on the part of the employer.
SECTORAL MISALLOCATION
As explained above, firms are not made fully accountable for their employment decisions. One aspect of this is their abusive reliance on short-term contracts, which in France are responsible for an eleven-billion-euro shortfall in unemployment insurance payments relative to unemployment benefits paid out (the yearly deficit on unemployment insurance is four billion euros). A case in point with much media coverage is the employment regime for entertainment workers (intermittents du spectacle, which include media employees) where this deficit has run to about one billion euros a year for the past fifteen years. Its official goal—the promotion of culture—has been much abused (aid to culture should be focused first of all on cultural works that we want to encourage—in the form of transparent subsidies rather than murky general payments). Employers in this sector welcome the system, as they are heavily subsidized by other sectors—who are of course unaware of the cross-subsidy. Audiovisual production companies use temporary workers and pay them rather low salaries. Workers oscillate between spells of short-term employment and unemployment covered by the unemployment insurance system. The political power of the sector has so far deterred politicians from reforming the scheme. In other countries, too, there are examples of powerful sectors overly reliant on badly paid short-term or contingent work, where exactly the same kind of hidden subsidies to one group of employers from others are involved.
ANOTHER INSTANCE OF FRENCH EXCEPTIONALISM: COLLUSION BETWEEN MANAGEMENT AND LABOR AT THE EXPENSE OF SOCIETY
Relations between employers and employees are mediocre in France … except when it comes to colluding at the expense of the taxpayer. As always, economic agents react to the incentives they confront. The real guilty parties are the French labor market institutions encouraging management and employees to manipulate the system.
First of all, employers and employees have learned to systematically transform resignations into dismissals. Unlike a dismissal, a resignation does not give the employee the right to receive unemployment benefits. Companies and their employees thus have an interest in conspiring against the unemployment insurance system by presenting voluntary departures as dismissals. So long as the employee promises to give up his rights to sue the firm and leaves the company “on good terms,” this redesignation costs the company nothing, as it pays none of the unemployment benefits that the employee will receive after the “dismissal.”
In fact, employers and employees do not even have to game the system now, as this collusion was made legal in 2008 through the introduction of “termination by mutual consent,” a procedure that allows an employer and an employee with a permanent contract to agree on the conditions for breaking the work contract between them. This law made it easier to disguise a resignation as a dismissal. Its popularity (more than 358,000 terminations by mutual consent in 2015!) is thus not surprising.
This measure also has implications for the effective retirement age, possibly bringing it forward by as much as three years. When it was first implemented in 2009, French labor economists Pierre Cahuc and André Zylberberg noted:
The possibility of breaking a contract by mutual consent allows an employer and an employee to separate on good terms. The devil is in the details: insofar as the employee will end up keeping unemployment payments for three years, in reality the government has just made it possible to retire at fifty-seven! An older worker will in fact be able to leave a job almost without monetary loss by having the unemployment insurance system finance what amounts to an early retirement.35
Let us note that this collusion against the unemployment insurance system would not take place if the company were made accountable by a reward-penalty system. This would make it expensive for a company to have a former worker unemployed or in pseudoretirement, and so there would be less of this manipulation of the system.
Another way that management and labor evade the law is the transformation of a redundancy on economic grounds (sometimes of a whole group) into a dismissal for personal reasons.36 In this case, the termination is desired by the employer: Pierre Cahuc and Francis Kramarz observed in 2005 that
all the testimonies obtained from CEOs, labor union officials, and directors of human resources suggest that dismissals for personal reasons are frequently economic dismissals in disguise. For the employer, the alibi of the personal motive makes it possible to avoid the procedures required for dismissal on economic grounds, even when the dismissal of a group of employees is involved; the employer is thus encouraged to adduce a personal reason for firing a worker, even if it means making a transaction with the employee so that the latter gives up his right of recourse in exchange for an indemnity. The employee then accepts particularly advantageous severance conditions.37
These behaviors underline the firm’s lack of accountability for the cost its actions impose on the unemployment insurance system. In 2013, there were thirty-eight thousand dismissals per month for personal reasons, as compared with sixteen thousand for economic reasons. About three-quarters of the dismissals for personal reasons were undisputed.
As in any insurance system, subsidies between sectors would be justified if the goal were to insure people in a particular career against a crisis affecting only their sector. It is much less justified when there are systematic transfers, as this kind of continuing cross-subsidy distorts the allocation or activity among sectors of the economy. Finally, note that this problem would also disappear with the introduction of a reward-penalty system.
THE EFFECT OF UNEMPLOYMENT ON OTHER INSTITUTIONS
In the context of high unemployment, protecting jobs becomes a major concern, to the point that it affects more or less every aspect of economic policy. As an example, consider the French bankruptcy law. In relation to its foreign counterparts, France is anomalous, as its law does little to protect creditors and is very favorable to shareholders and managers. Moreover—to my point—this legislation is motivated by a desire to save jobs. The underlying idea is that if the company gets into difficulties, jobs will be more likely to be saved if control is left in the hands of the directors of the company rather than the creditors. However, first of all, there is no theoretical support and still less empirical evidence confirming the thesis that French institutions protect jobs.38 The directors may in fact be responsible for the company’s troubles. The people who have not been able to manage the company are not necessarily those best equipped to manage the fate of the employees concerned. Moreover, the partners may take undue risks (thus endangering jobs) in an attempt to overcome the difficulties. There is therefore no clear reason why the current system would preserve jobs.
Above all, job creation is actually neglected here. If the weak protection given creditors has a negative impact on the financing and growth of companies, which is likely, the law’s net effect on employment is certainly negative.
In the case of other countries, it might be merger control that is affected by a misplaced idea that this area of policy can be used to preserve employment—for example, by allowing an anticompetitive merger to go ahead if the bidders argue they can save a failing company. But if the target company is in difficulties, any new management would need to look at redundancies in any event.
WHAT CAN REFORM ACHIEVE AND HOW CAN IT BE IMPLEMENTED SUCCESSFULLY?
The transition from protecting jobs to protecting employees, making companies accountable and giving them more flexibility while reducing the role of the courts, does not sit comfortably with the French tradition of economic planning. Furthermore, we must be wary of transition effects. What gains could be expected from a reform? Which factors are likely to contribute to its success? No matter how intellectually coherent it may be, the proposal to make businesses more accountable needs to be made operational. For example, reform must be socially acceptable and sustainable, and careful thought needs to be given to transition. The specifics here concern France, but the wider point is universal: labor market reform is always sensitive because it involves social relations and people’s livelihoods.
WHAT IMPACT CAN BE EXPECTED FROM A REFORM OF THE LABOR MARKET?
The idea that making it easier for French companies to lay off employees could lead to a reduction in unemployment is counterintuitive to many. Indeed, two forces are involved: on the one hand, making layoffs easier increases dismissals of workers with permanent contracts; and on the other, employers reassured by the increased flexibility will hire more workers on permanent contracts.39 So what are the benefits to be expected from increased flexibility?
The first benefit is better jobs. As we have seen, the current system has many inefficiencies: long-term unemployment; poor matching of employees and jobs when employees who are looking for new challenges, or who don’t get along with their coworkers, or whose functions have simply become redundant, stay in the same job; the absence of a way for workers the employer wants to keep on to move from a fixed-term contract to a permanent contract; and finally the length of the legal procedures and the uncertainty that hang over both employer and employee when it comes to redundancies. Better jobs either mean more productive businesses (thus creating more jobs), or greater well-being in the workplace, or both.
The second benefit would be a lower burden on public finances and unemployment insurance. Today, the succession of fixed-term contracts and unemployment, the terminations by mutual agreement, and long-term unemployment all result either in tax increases or increases in employers’ social charges, neither of which helps reduce unemployment.
SUSTAINABLE REFORM
Like all major reforms, job market reform has to be maintained over the long term. If it is to be effective, employers have to believe in its sustainability. But companies might legitimately be concerned about the state’s ability to make a genuine commitment to reform the employment contract. Will future governments keep the current government’s promises? Companies must not fear that hires under a new system will in the near future be transformed into old-style permanent contracts when the parliamentary majority changes.
As always, the state’s ability to keep its promises contributes to the success of its policies. Thus a minimal political consensus regarding the necessity of changing the employment rules is necessary. Employment is a national issue, and we can hope that a bipartisan agreement could be negotiated in order to finally remedy the problem of unemployment and social exclusion. Again, the point applies to any country making major labor market reforms. Germany’s “Hartz Reforms” in 2003 did have cross-party consensus, for example; and although the reforms still have their critics, Germany’s unemployment rate was just 3.9 percent in mid-2017.
THE NEED FOR A GRADUAL TRANSITION
From this point of view, it is important to make sure that workers currently in a good position in the labor market (in France, those with permanent jobs) do not lose out as a result of reform. Once again drawing lessons from experiments in the area of taxing pollution,40 it is possible to grant “grandfathered rights” to workers’ existing contracts; those would hence remain under the old law concerning dismissals, whereas all the new contracts would fall under the new law. That is exactly what Matteo Renzi did in Italy in 2014.41
Of course, even protected by grandfathered rights, these privileged workers might still feel concern. They might fear future promotions would give priority to employees under the new contract if they did not themselves convert to the latter; and, like their employers, they might worry about the state’s ability to make long-term commitments and fear, at some time in the future, the complete abolition of the old contracts, thus affecting those who had retained this status. That said, the increased likelihood of finding a new job under the new system, and better prospects for their children finding work, should overcome these concerns.
Another reason why one might want to grant grandfathered rights to employees with permanent jobs is that one could imagine an immediate wave of dismissals related to jobs that companies wanted to make redundant but have been unable to. More generally, the transition from the initial situation of the labor market, which necessarily takes time to improve following a reform, must be considered carefully. For instance, workers on the new contracts who are fired might still remain, on average, too long unemployed; it would probably be desirable to introduce the reward-penalty system gradually until unemployment has been reduced.
EDUCATING PEOPLE AND MAKING REFORM SOCIALLY ACCEPTABLE
This proposal for reforming the French labor market is less drastic than the flexi-security found in, say, Denmark (which has no reward-penalty system). Even so, one of its main attractions, the flexibility granted to employers, will also be perceived by many French people as its principal defect. And a reward-penalty system might not dispel objections. The French public’s general diffidence toward economic levers (such as a carbon tax or a reward-penalty system) that make economic agents accountable for their actions constitutes an obstacle to reform. In fact, for many French people, the idea that a business might pay to fire employees is still taboo, because it seems to endorse a behavior (firing employees) that is considered immoral.
There are two responses to this ambivalence: first of all, today it is the companies that do not fire workers that pay most of the social cost, while those doing the firing bear only a small fraction of it (namely the severance pay). Formulating the problem in moral terms consequently leads to a slippery slope with respect to moral evaluation. Secondly, the same taboo existed twenty or thirty years ago with regard to environmental taxation, which has now become commonplace. Economists who claimed that environmental taxation (or the introduction of markets for tradable emission rights) produced environmental benefits and diminished the cost of compliance, used to hear the same refrain in response: “Paying to pollute would be immoral!” But was it more moral not to pay when one polluted? In the end, environmental taxation became acceptable for the majority of the public and is now widespread. An analogous development could, of course, be envisaged for the right to dismiss employees.42
The poor functioning of the labor market in southern Europe is hard to ignore, and has indeed been evident for a long time (even though it has gotten worse due to the impact of the financial and European crises). It is the economist’s job to try to understand the resistance to change in light of this. When dysfunctional labor market institutions are still supported by a majority of citizens, it is not surprising that governments are in no hurry to explore controversial reforms and that they rather use the same old quick fixes to fight unemployment. It is easy for citizens to understand that their company could more easily terminate their permanent employment contracts if employers get more flexibility; it is much harder for these employees, as well as for the unemployed and employees in precarious jobs, to identify and analyze the economic mechanism that results in a more flexible system creating more numerous and better jobs.
The complexity of economic mechanisms is not the only obstacle. The prominence of redundancies made on economic grounds and their impact in the media and politics are also responsible for lukewarm public opinion about greater labor market flexibility. The employee fired in connection with redundancies has a face and experiences a tragedy (a very real one, because the labor market might never allow him or her to get another, similar job). On the other hand, the large number of good jobs that are not created every day as a result of businesses’ reluctance to create more permanent positions affects nameless people: no one who is unemployed or employed on a fixed-term contract can identify with a job that has never been created. Job losses make the headlines, job creation much less so (except when politicians can plausibly take credit for them), and a lack of job creation is by its very nature invisible.
The phenomenon of the identifiable victim, much studied by psychologists,43 refers to the observation that individuals feel much more empathy toward clearly identified victims (to the point of being prepared to help them) than toward victims defined more vaguely (“statistical victims”). For example, citizens are prepared to donate considerable sums to relieve the suffering of a person whose image and story they have seen on television, but are less disposed to help anonymous victims who have a greater need of their money. In the domain of the labor market, the identified victims are employees suffering from mass layoffs, and the anonymous victims are the unemployed for whom no job has been created.
THE OTHER GREAT DEBATES ABOUT EMPLOYMENT
MULTIPLE CAUSES OF UNEMPLOYMENT
Although it is emblematic, the character of the labor contract is not solely responsible for the current situation of high unemployment in southern Europe. For example, among other criticisms commonly directed at French institutions are the following:
• the mediocrity and cost of ongoing vocational training coprovided by management and labor, training that does not target the right categories of employees, includes only a small portion of programs that lead to widely recognized diplomas or certificates, but that, along with apprenticeships, nonetheless absorb thirty-two billion euros per year, or 1.6 percent of GDP;44
• the insufficient number of apprenticeships45 and work-study programs;
• the gap between the skills provided by schools and the needs of companies (indeed, the high unemployment rate coincides with real shortages of labor for certain kinds of jobs);
• redistribution in favor of low-income workers primarily through the channel of the minimum wage (which is the highest in the European Union) rather than through the tax system—that is, through a tax credit on income from work (like the Earned Income Tax Credit in the US or the UK’s tax credit system);
• the management of the unemployed (usually called active labor market policy), which is very different from that of the Scandinavian countries, for example, where the unemployed are given greater incentives to resume work. Also, the replacement rate—the ratio of unemployment benefits to earnings from employment—is around the European average, but it is much more generous for workers with high salaries (three times higher than in Germany, for instance);
• the management of the public employment service (it is symptomatic that employers resort to Le Bon coin—a free Internet want-ads site—to recruit employees, despite a very extensive public employment service);
• the lack of flexibility in contractual arrangements, with rules being set mostly at the sector (rather than the firm) level;
• the closed nature of certain professions (for example, taxi driving), which prevents the creation of jobs many people would want to do.
The other countries of southern Europe (Spain, Italy, Portugal, Greece), which have similar institutions and the same causes producing the same effects, have equally disastrous (or even worse) unemployment statistics than France, in particular unemployment among the young. Some of the points would apply to economies with more flexible jobs markets, but the combination explains the huge gap in unemployment rates between southern Europe (including France) and other OECD economies.
Several books would be required to deal thoroughly with all these issues. Here I will limit myself to a few remarks.
REDUCING WORKING HOURS: A FALSE SOLUTION
Economists widely reject46 the fallacious claim that there is a fixed quantity of employment, a concept according to which the total number of jobs in an economy is fixed and thus must be distributed equitably (the “lump of labor fallacy”). The introduction of the thirty-five-hour work week in France in 2000, which had received no significant support from professional economists and which sought to create jobs by spreading the work around, took people by surprise. And yet the idea that employment is scarce is age old and regularly resurfaces, particularly in periods of recession. Paradoxically (given that it tends to be favored on the left of the political spectrum), the idea that there is a fixed amount of work—and so working time should be reduced in order to allow the employment to be shared—is the same one that underlies the discourse of far-right parties when they claim that immigrants “take employment away” from resident nationals. Others use it to advocate lowering the retirement age (don’t older workers take work away from the young?). Still others use it in support of protectionist goals (don’t foreign companies take away our jobs?). Finally, others worried about the impact on available work in 1996, when it was decided to end compulsory military service in France.
Where does the idea that work is scarce, and that the government must intervene to distribute it, come from? Indirectly, from Malthus. At the beginning of the nineteenth century, the scarce resource was still largely land. Land was more or less limited in quantity, and thus jobs working the earth were limited as well. Of course, work has always required not only labor, but also complementary factors of production, for example machine tools, premises, computers, or factories. But unlike the production factor that Malthus focused on (land), these production factors are not at all fixed in quantity, at least in the medium and long term. Even in the short term, production factors can be adjusted in certain circumstances. In a famous article,47 David Card (now at the University of California, Berkeley) studied the impact of 125,000 Cuban migrants who came to Miami in the space of a few months in 1980. This migration, of significant magnitude in relation to the size of Miami (7 percent increase in the labor force), had practically no impact on either unemployment or on the salaries of the groups competing with the Cuban immigrants on the labor market (essentially African Americans). Work was not fixed in quantity; investments in textile production quickly created the necessary jobs.
In the case of sharing work time, the reasoning is slightly different. Suppose there is a legal obligation to reduce working time that favors employees and disadvantages companies—for instance, no change in salary (in practice, the reduction in work time is often accompanied by changes in salary agreements or state subsidies—we will return to this possibility). In the short term, it is possible that employment will increase in order to compensate for the reduction in working hours so as to meet the orders on hand and to make use of existing factors of production. However, this is a flash in the pan; in the medium term, the order book, other inputs, and employment adjust downward. Yet a sustainable employment policy has to create jobs over the medium and long term. Furthermore, the cost of public policies to compensate employers, if adopted, must be taken into account too, because taxes will have to be increased or public expenditures decreased elsewhere.
This brings me to the methodology used to measure the effects of policies, which requires rigorous econometric analyses. As we have seen, a change in labor supply or demand (such as a reduction in working time or a wave of migration) never occurs in isolation. At the same time, the economy may be growing or in recession, and thus unemployment may naturally be receding or expanding independent of the policy change; moreover, supporting measures may be introduced. Even if we limit ourselves to measuring the short-term effects, we must insulate the effect of the reduction in work time or of the resulting increase in the active population from the change in other factors influencing employment. Thus, David Card took into account the fact that the unemployment rate was increasing at the time of the Cuban exodus, along with other factors; similarly, to measure the effect of the thirty-five-hour work week, we have to correct for the effect of the economic cycle (which was favorable from 1998 to 2002), the supporting measures helping create jobs (fiscal measures, agreements on salary moderation, other dimensions of a reform package),48 etc. Studies properly identifying the causal impact49 of migration or policies of reducing working time (such as in Quebec and Germany, and in France in 1981 and in 2000–2002) are thus necessary. The few studies we have do not seem to show, even over the short term, job destruction related to migration, or job creation connected with the reduction of working time,50 in contrast to what we would expect if work were a fixed quantity.
This fallacious idea that work has a fixed quantity also crops up in attitudes toward technological progress. Employment changes continually. For at least two centuries we have been afraid that automation—from weaving looms (the revolt of the Luddites in England in the early nineteenth century) to assembly lines in the 1950s, and more recently robotics—might cause employment to disappear. All these technological changes lead in fact to the disappearance of certain jobs, but fortunately not to the disappearance of employment (otherwise we would all be unemployed). Similarly, studies show that migrants bring economic benefits to a country, including for its workers in terms of more jobs and higher economic growth, with very little or no effect on earnings.51 Needless to say, this is just a broad-brush picture, as precise effects depend on the context (such as migrants’ skills, labor market and welfare institutions, and the complementarity or substitutability between immigrants and natives in the job market).52
Let there be no mistake: economists never take sides on the question of whether people should work thirty-five, eighteen, or forty-five hours a week. That is a choice to be made by society … and by the persons concerned. On this last point, there is no reason why, left free to determine their working time (as is the case for independent workers), different people should make the same choice; some would rather have more free time than a higher income, while others will prefer the opposite. At the same time, the idea that laws reducing working time, lowering the retirement age, blocking immigration, adopting protectionist measures, or reintroducing military service will create jobs for others has no foundation, either theoretical or empirical.
PROTECTIONISM: ANOTHER FALSE SOLUTION
Employees affected by technological and economic change must be given help. Although these changes are inevitable, the individuals concerned nonetheless suffer major human costs in the short run. They cannot necessarily find new jobs similar to those that are destroyed. Consider the vexing issue of trade between the United States and China. While beneficial to Americans as a whole, serious difficulties have been experienced by regions like the Midwest.53 The influx of Chinese imports has directly harmed competing American companies specializing in certain kinds of manufacturing (together with their local economies) much more than it has the American economy as a whole.54
This brings me to the issue of protectionism. Around the world, populist politicians are riding the wave of popular indignation against job losses or falling wages for unskilled workers. This indignation reflects real difficulties: governments have not paid enough attention to the damage caused to some of their citizens by globalization. Until 1990, international trade created relatively few losers. Since then, developing countries—notably China—have turned their backs on their earlier protectionist policies of import substitution and have opted instead for a market-driven and open economy. Simultaneously, container transport costs have fallen drastically. These two phenomena have realigned trade to take place along the global north-south axis. Whilst developed countries are winners overall, many of their workers, often unskilled, are experiencing difficulties finding jobs close to home similar to the ones that have gone. And retraining policies to increase their skills and equip them for other jobs have not kept up.
In the global south, growth helps score points in the fight against poverty. Between 1991 and 2015, GDP per inhabitant rose by 326 percent for India and 823 percent for China. This is unprecedented development in the history of humankind. But this good news brings no comfort to Americans or Britons whose salaries have stagnated during the same period, nor for the French who have lost their jobs in a depressed labor market.
Yet, protectionism can wave no magic wand. It can only encourage retaliatory measures by trading partners: if everyone looks after number one, things will not improve overall—it will even make them worse. Protectionism takes away the benefits of international specialization, and it removes the stimulus of competition, which pushes companies to improve themselves rather than profit from captive consumers. Protectionism will not deal with the challenges of digital technology either: by exploiting productivity gains, automation poses an employment problem even bigger than that associated with globalization.
THE URGENCY
French (or, more generally, southern European) labor market institutions deviate from the international norm. They are supposed to protect employees, but in fact they may weaken them by putting them at risk of exclusion and marginalization. To understand this unintended consequence, we have to look beyond appearances, and that is the first message of this chapter.
In the past, the dysfunctional nature of France’s labor market institutions was not as obvious. The growth of the trente glorieuses (the thirty years of prosperity following World War II) made it possible to create new jobs, and the soundness of public finances allowed for government support. Today, France, along with neighbors such as Spain and Italy, is confronted by a “perfect storm”; three challenges will exacerbate the problem of unemployment.
1. Public finances. With a public debt of 100 percent of the GDP, France’s public finances continue to deteriorate. As we have seen, current employment policy is very costly. If the country’s solvency were called into question, the whole welfare state would be at risk. Reducing unemployment and thus the cost of public employment policy would help gain control over public finances.
THE COMPLEXITY OF THE FRENCH LABOR CODE
In another example of France’s exceptionalism when it comes to the labor market, French labor law is both complex and directive. Complex: everyone agrees. The French labor code is 3,200 pages long and continues to grow as the years go by. Even highly specialized professors of labor law do not fully master it. Hence, the adage “ignorance of the law is no excuse,” which normally makes perfect sense, becomes almost laughable in this context. Do we really expect the CEO of a small or middle-sized company, who has no specialized legal department and who is busy with other tasks, to be able to master this legal corpus? Even a large company with a solid legal department is capable of violating labor law without knowing it.
The directive aspect of French labor law is more controversial. France remains one of the countries where the state and industry bodies intervene the most in contractual relationships between employers and employees. Elsewhere, there is more room for negotiations between employers and employees (Great Britain) or between sector bodies and employees (the Scandinavian countries). Some countries (Denmark) have virtually no labor law, giving contractual arrangements free rein and thus more opportunities to adapt their employment relations to the specific context of a business or sector.
To be sure, the French legislature has provided some room for negotiation at the level of sectors and enterprises. In particular, since 2004, a company-level agreement can deviate from the sector agreement if the latter does not explicitly rule it out. However, in practice there are very few such deviations from the norm, the hierarchy of rules being: 1) the labor code, 2) the sector agreement, 3) the company agreement. Sectoral agreements are systematically extended by the Ministry of Labor in such a way that the possibility of a distinct company agreement becomes moot. Sector agreements may solve the problem of free-riding in the provision of ongoing vocational training, but they also allow member companies to come to agreements among themselves and to make the final consumer pay the increase in costs (especially in sectors not subject to international competition); in the latter respect, they are bad for demand and thus for employment.55 Because of the quasi-systematic extension of sector agreements, more than 90 percent of French employees are covered by collective conventions, compared to only 1 percent in Germany.56
This obviously does not mean that sectors should play no role in labor contracts. Management and labor unions in a company do not always have the expertise necessary to draw up contracts, or a clear view of their consequences, especially in small and medium-sized enterprises. The sectors thus have an important role to play as providers of services to help management and labor organize their relations better, or by conceiving sectoral agreements that are an option rather than a constraint on negotiations within the enterprise.
Finally, let us note that even when sector or company agreements are extensive, the labor code can still play an important role as in the case of a minimum wage.57
2. Immigration. The 2015 European migrant crisis has renewed many people’s concerns about a shortage of jobs; no matter how considerable it seems to be, this crisis is only a prelude to what will happen if we do not succeed in controlling global warming.58 However, migrants represent an economic as well as cultural opportunity for any country. They must therefore be welcomed as contributors to society, which requires that they not be excluded from jobs by labor market institutions—yet another reason to reform these institutions.
3. Technology. The digital revolution59 will have two effects that exacerbate the social cost of rigidities. First of all, it increases the speed at which employment is being transformed and jobs destroyed and created, making the overly rigid permanent contracts even less attractive for employers than they are today, and increasing the need for better ongoing vocational retraining. Second, work is itself in the process of changing, with a growing number of self-employed people and individuals working for several employers. Many observers are calling for the creation of a worker’s law rather than a more restrictive employee’s law. French labor law, as massive as it is, focuses almost exclusively on the employee, and is based on a conception of work that dates from employment in factories. Consequently, France has a long way to go to prepare itself for the changes ahead. And while France stands out for the rigidity of its labor market institutions, the same point applies to every other developed economy. Even in the flexible US, UK, or Danish labor markets, the legal and regulatory frameworks center around employees rather than workers.
While labor market institutions vary a great deal over time and between countries, the experience of France offers insights for all: All countries face legitimate concerns about the future of work and will need to resist populists appearing to wave a magic wand. All need to understand the unintended consequences of well-intentioned policies, and why it is better to protect workers than to protect jobs.
Have we really tried everything to stop high unemployment? I strongly doubt it. In this chapter, I have tried to explain why and to indicate paths toward reform. Migration, globalization, and technology all make it urgent that we take action.