Frank A. Nankivell, “The Central Bank” from Puck (detail), February 2, 1910.
The War of Wealth (detail), ca. 1895.
IN AUGUST 1873, IGNATIUS DONNELLY,
a Minnesota journalist and agitator, warned his fellow Americans that the United States was becoming a plutocracy—a government by and for the wealthy who enslaved the nation’s “producing population.” The engine of this plutocracy was “a vicious monetary system of which the national banks are the source.” Donnelly preached the need to restore economic opportunity to ordinary Americans. His calls for change would become even more urgent and angry over the ensuing months, as a crippling depression, partly triggered by the collapse of the famed investment bank Jay Cooke & Company in New York City in September 1873, descended on the nation. The people, he urged, educated and aroused to action, would have to take their country back at the ballot box and restore the government of the republic to its rightful place in Washington, D.C., since greedy bankers had set up their plutocracy elsewhere: “Its headquarters are established in Wall Street,” Donnelly asserted, “where … [it] rules the nation more despotically than under the old pro-slavery regime.”1
Donnelly’s was not a lone voice. In the years after the Civil War, an array of reformers and activists tailored old Jacksonian fears about the power of banks to new financial and social realities. Although the movement ultimately gained its greatest momentum among farmers and townspeople in the West and South, even New Yorkers took part. In 1876, for example, Peter Cooper, a New York City inventor, manufacturer, and philanthropist, ran as the presidential candidate of the small Independent Greenback Party against the Republican Rutherford Hayes and the Democrat Samuel Tilden. Although the 85-year-old Cooper attracted a mere 81,000 votes nationwide, less than 1 percent of the ballots cast for president, he continued to sound warnings that echoed Donnelly’s. In an open letter to President Hayes in 1877, Cooper beseeched him to “lead the people from a threatened bondage that now hangs over the liberties and the happiness of the American people”—a bondage to the “money-power” of the 2,000-odd banks scattered across the country. Cooper’s and Donnelly’s assertions were persuasive to many in New York City’s burgeoning labor movement who viewed the nation’s industrial economy as a battleground between “producers” (those who created real value by making handicrafts and industrial goods or harvesting crops) and “nonproducers” (greedy employers, lawyers, speculators, and bankers who manipulated prices, workers’ wages, and credit without creating real commodities themselves). Into the mid-1880s, New York members of the Knights of Labor and the Central Labor Union proclaimed their opposition to the “money power” and banker control of the currency; in the nation’s first Labor Day parade in Union Square in 1882, workers carried placards demanding “NO MONEY MONOPOLY.”2

“Bread Currency,” 1876.
Cooper Union Archives
This leaflet in the form of a three-dollar bill from “The Bank of Bread” publicized the campaign of the Independent Greenback Party presidential candidate, New Yorker Peter Cooper, and his running mate, former Ohio congressman Samuel F. Cary, in 1876.
The power of Wall Street was undeniably real, and the city’s very rise to national primacy owed much to the ability of its bankers to attract and redirect the nation’s wealth and generate new wealth. Many Americans feared the unsettling changes that accompanied this financial growth. For them, “big business” meant a new economy in which a small number of large corporations dominated markets; violent strikes pitted labor unions against bank-financed railroads and mining companies; prosperity periodically gave way to devastating “crashes”; and the luxuries of 60-room mansions contrasted starkly with the miseries of overcrowded tenements, or for that matter, with the modest virtues of middle-class homes. More broadly, many ordinary Americans were troubled by an economy that seemed increasingly beyond their control. In this new post-Civil War America, complex, incomprehensible, and hidden forces appeared to be interfering with the free operation of the laws of supply and demand that had governed an older, arguably simpler national economy. For many Americans bewildered or frustrated by economic change, the accumulation of economic power in the hands of railroad “tycoons,” large industrialists, and financiers was both the source and the symbol of these unsettling developments. Consequently, many took alarm at the concentrated and seemingly inscrutable power that bankers and their associates now possessed, viewed as a threat to the nation’s very survival as a democratic republic. While Boston, Philadelphia, Chicago, and other major cities also concentrated this power, they appeared as mere spokes to the hub of New York City.
Over the next 35 years, Cooper’s argument that New York bankers were wringing economic and political power out of “the toiling masses of the American people” resonated in the thinking and activism of numerous American radicals, insurgents, writers, politicians, and voters. Several generations of reformers—Greenbackers between the late 1860s and the 1880s, Populists in the 1890s, and “progressives” in the 1900s and 1910s—viewed Manhattan as a financial octopus whose tentacles threatened to entangle ordinary Americans from coast to coast. Some critics denounced Wall Street in order to contain what they saw as new urban threats to older American values, including the alleged greed and influence of foreigners and Jews or the threat of a monopolistic “Money Trust.” Some offered relatively sophisticated plans to remake or regulate Wall Street “for the people” by expanding the currency supply in order to lower interest rates for ordinary borrowers, raise the prices paid to farmers and small business owners, and prevent financial panics and depressions.3
Yet the sheer centrality and reach of New York’s banks in the nation’s economy meant that most efforts at reform—whether through elections, legislation, official inquests, or new regulatory bodies—achieved minimal success. Wall Street banks continued to play an unrivaled role in accumulating wealth and shaping the country’s financial, commercial, and industrial growth, despite the most strenuous efforts of critics who saw them as dangerously omnipotent. Ironically, it was New York bankers themselves—buoyed by their growing influence and power, and troubled by the inefficiency and economic damage triggered by dramatic swings in the availability of credit and currency—who became the most successful reformers of their own institutions. The longest-lasting financial innovation to emerge from this era of ferment—the creation of the Federal Reserve System in 1913—would largely be the work of New York financiers. Thus, as Americans grappled with unprecedented economic change, New York’s banks and bankers would be critical actors as well as symbols and targets.

Bread Winners Bank, ca. 1886. Cast iron. Designed by Charles A. Bailey for J. & E. Stevens Company, Cromwell, Connecticut.
Fine Art Collection – Citi Center for Culture
Charles Bailey designed this mechanical bank to address the contemporary “Labor question.” According to Bailey, the toy champions the honest worker, who gains a penny from “a capitalist holding on to a club which represents monopoly” while a “boodler” (a corrupt politician or businessman) lurks nearby.
Gold or Paper?
At the heart of reformers’ grievances in the late 1860s and 1870s was a heated disagreement over the future of the nation’s money supply: whether it would be based primarily on gold or would continue to include a large volume of greenbacks (the paper money first issued by the federal government during the Civil War). With few exceptions, leading bankers in New York and elsewhere believed gold coins and bullion to be the natural, most reliable, indeed the divinely ordained core of the world’s monetary systems. As a metal of limited quantity, gold was a sound basis for any currency, since its supply and hence its value would not fluctuate unpredictably. In a stable and proper gold-based system, the quantity and value of paper money issued into circulation would be tied closely to the quantity and value of gold reserves held in government and bank vaults. This guaranteed that creditors, including banks, would be repaid by borrowers in money that had not depreciated in value because of inflation. It was precisely the inflation of the Civil War years that led advocates of gold—or “sound money,” as they called it—to disparage greenbacks, or “soft money,” and emphasize the metal’s importance. With the federally issued paper money flooding the economy and driving up consumer prices, debtors who had borrowed, say, $500 could later repay it with $500 in greenbacks that bought far less, a situation bankers viewed as unfair and dishonest. Additionally, holders of federal bonds issued during the Civil War—a group including ordinary Americans, but also many banks—wanted to be paid in gold rather than in depreciated greenbacks when they cashed out their investments at the U.S. Treasury. In New York, Boston, and the other eastern seaports, moreover, bankers and their merchant clients understood gold to be the safest and most efficient medium of exchange for international trade. English and many other European merchants and bankers expected Americans to pay for goods with gold, or with currency or credits whose value was closely tied to gold.
Consequently, most New York bankers wanted the federal government to resume the gold standard that had been abandoned in December 1861, when New York banks, the U.S. Treasury, and then the rest of the nation’s banks stopped paying out gold in exchange for paper currency as an emergency measure during the Civil War. Resumption of gold payments by the Treasury—the return to the gold standard—meant that the federal government would limit the amount of paper money in circulation so that the gold dollar coin and the paper dollar bill would be equivalent and exchangeable in value, buying the same amount of merchandise in the marketplace and guaranteeing the “honest” repayment of what debtors owed their creditors. Although bankers and other advocates of “sound money” embraced a wide variety of opinions about the timing and details of gold resumption, many believed that the government’s legal tender greenbacks would have to be reduced drastically, leaving National Bank Notes (a separate form of paper currency controlled by the National Banks established during the war) to circulate alongside gold (and some silver) coins. The most adamant “sound money” advocates embraced the “cremation theory of resumption,” under which the Treasury would burn the greenbacks it received in payments and exchanges to ensure that they would never reenter circulation.8

Leading bankers in New York and elsewhere believed gold coins and bullion to be the natural, most reliable, indeed the divinely ordained core of the world's monetary systems.

Pursuing the Counterfeiters
The Secret Service Cleans up New York City
In 1865, the Secret Service, the newly created anticounterfeiting police force of the U.S. Treasury, opened its New York headquarters at 63 Bleecker Street. The New York office soon became the official record center and institutional heart of the Secret Service, where it operated close to New York’s criminal underworld and far from the oversight of Washington. By 1870, the agency had officially relocated to New York, where headquarters was just blocks from the East Houston Street saloons, “boozing-kens” where New York’s leading counterfeiters conducted meetings, took orders, and made deals.
New York’s concentration of banks, bank note manufacturers, and financial expertise, as well as its dense underworld of crime and corruption, made it the obvious place from which to lead a counterfeiting operation. Before the Civil War, counterfeiting was a local matter. With thousands of unique bank notes in circulation, counterfeit bills did not need to be perfect copies, just good enough to fool overwhelmed shopkeepers. But with the creation of a national currency, counterfeiters had uniform bills to imitate, of equal value everywhere. In response, the country’s counterfeit economy consolidated itself into a series of loose networks, centered in New York.
The city’s counterfeiting operations were led by a handful of criminal entrepreneurs with the capital to print quality counterfeits and the connections to distribute them nationally. Joshua D. Miner exemplifies the postwar counterfeit ringleader. Miner was “a good-looking, civil man, of the ‘eminently respectable’ sort,” who lived in a stately house uptown on 67th Street. The source of his wealth was hundreds of thousands of dollars in counterfeit National Bank Notes produced at his “factory” on 49th Street and Sixth Avenue.4
Counterfeiters like Miner triggered a federal response. Because National Bank Notes were backed by the federal government, counterfeits were seen as a direct affront to federal authority. And like New York’s legitimate bank notes, counterfeit notes issued by Joshua Miner were distributed nationwide. Furthermore, Miner worked as a building contractor for New York’s city government, then firmly under the control of Boss William M. Tweed’s corrupt Tammany Hall machine, insulating him from local police. By 1871, the Secret Service had done serious damage to New York’s counterfeiters, but Miner’s wealth, social status, and cautious dealing made him a difficult target.
With field offices in 11 American cities, the Secret Service represented an unprecedented projection of federal power into local communities accustomed to policing themselves. Though it had immediate success in breaking up counterfeiting networks, the agency encountered considerable resistance, in part due to the controversial methods of its founder, the unlikely bureaucrat William P. Wood. Wood was short, ugly, and crafty, a tireless self-promoter who used his connections in the Lincoln administration to secure a position as superintendent of the federal Old Capital Prison in Washington. This allowed Wood to build relationships within both the federal government and the criminal underworld. After the war, Wood used his connections to take over the government’s anticounterfeiting efforts and create the Secret Service. Nearly half of his initial recruits had criminal backgrounds, and some went straight from prison to the federal payroll. Wood’s agents accepted bribes, sold confiscated counterfeits for personal profit, ignored procedure and law alike, and alienated local police departments, courts, and the public. But Wood’s operatives also produced results, arresting over 200 counterfeiters in 1865 alone.5
In the early 1870s, Wood’s successor, Hiram Whitley, consolidated these gains. Whitley professionalized the Secret Service, hiring middle-class recruits and phasing out Wood’s more controversial tactics. In fall 1871, Whitley finally went after Joshua Miner. Among the dozens of counterfeiters by then languishing in New York’s jails, Whitley found an accomplice willing to “squeal”—Harry Cole. That October, Cole arrived outside Joshua Miner’s house with $1,500 provided by Whitley. Shortly thereafter, the talented bank note engraver Thomas Ballard materialized out of the shadows with two valuable counterfeit plates, used to engrave bank notes. As soon as Cole completed the deal with Miner, the Secret Service pounced. Miner fought furiously, flinging Cole’s money into the darkness, but he was quickly overpowered.
In prosecuting those he caught, Whitley faced a double bind. To secure conviction, he needed to catch counterfeiters in the act, which was difficult without criminal informants. But informants’ testimony was deeply mistrusted by the courts, as was the testimony of Secret Service operatives. In the words of the judge in the Miner case, “as a class” the evidence of government detectives “is always to be scrutinized, and accepted with caution.” Tried before the U.S. District Court in New York City, Miner was found innocent—Cole’s money, the jury concluded, had not been found on Miner’s person, but on the ground nearby. It was an incredible victory for Miner, who had spent nearly his entire fortune on his defense at the trial, though he was shaken enough to abandon counterfeiting for good.6
Hiram Whitley expanded the reach of the Secret Service significantly, instructing his officers to pursue “not only counterfeiting and other frauds upon the Treasury, but … all crimes coming within the jurisdiction of the Department of Justice,” including fraud, smuggling, and the activities of the Ku Klux Klan. As a journalist noted in 1873, although the Secret Service was “terra incognita to most people,” it was nonetheless “a gigantic machine, having its ramifications everywhere … a powerful instrument for good or evil, according to the hands that guide it.” In 1874 the headquarters of the Secret Service returned to Washington. Yet the legacy of the Secret Service’s first decade lives on in continuing federal intervention in the world of finance, bringing the long arm of the federal government back to New York City.7

“The Breaking of the Counterfeiters’ Ring,” National Police Gazette. Published in Sins of New York as “Exposed” by the Police Gazette, by Edward Van Every (New York: Frederick A. Stokes Co., 1930).
Private Collection
—Bernard J. Lillis

New York’s banks played a vivid and sinister part in Greenback ideology.

Greenbackers had a diametrically opposed understanding of how things should work. For them, a limited gold supply meant that powerful bankers and creditors in New York and other large cities could control the entire economy to serve their own self-interest rather than the welfare of the American people. A contracting currency—a money supply that grew smaller as greenbacks were phased out and gold and National Bank Notes remained static—meant that ordinary farmers and small businesspeople would be squeezed to pay back loans in money that was more valuable than when they borrowed it, giving banks an extra and undeserved profit. As the amount of circulating currency decreased, debtors would also face deflated prices for the crops or goods they sold. Instead of appeasing gold plutocrats, Greenbackers argued, the U.S. government should protect the people by maintaining and if necessary expanding the issue of greenbacks to keep the money supply apace with population and economic growth.
New York’s banks played a vivid and sinister part in Greenback ideology. Greenbackers (and the Populists who followed them in the 1890s) did not always fully understand the mechanics of New York’s domination of the nation’s banking system, but they did grasp that the city’s banks played an outsized role in controlling the flow of available capital in ways that could hurt farmers and small businesspeople. Some currency reformers knew that Wall Street’s accumulation of deposit reserves from “country” banks—sanctioned by the National Banking Act of 1864—thwarted borrowers in the West and South. By requiring National Banks across the country to keep capital reserves in New York City banks, the 1864 law in effect siphoned money from banks in rural western and southern states and put it in the hands of Wall Street bankers.
The New Yorkers, in turn, profited by lending the reserves to brokers and speculators on the New York Stock Exchange and other exchanges. In the 1870s, these “call loans” were about one-third of all loans made by National Banks in New York City, and that proportion would increase to about half before the end of the century. While the call loans helped make the NYSE the nation’s securities marketplace and greatly fueled railroad and industrial expansion, they also shifted capital out of agriculture, thereby contributing to tighter credit and higher interest rates in many parts of the West and South. Meanwhile, when those western and southern banks called back surplus deposits from New York in the fall to finance the annual harvesting and shipment of crops, the resulting shortage of call loan money on Wall Street repeatedly helped trigger financial panics, runs on banks, market slumps, and economic depressions that spread from Manhattan to the rest of the nation—as they did in 1873 (and would do again in 1884, 1893, and 1907). For financial insurgents, the concentration of these rural bank deposits in New York—and the way they fed speculative fever in the stock market and disastrous cycles of boom and bust for everyone else—proved that a financial monopoly based in New York jeopardized the country’s well-being and survival.
The Populists Versus Wall Street
Though the movement faced a major defeat when Congress restored the gold standard and reduced the quantity of circulating greenbacks in 1879, the campaign for currency and banking reform continued. This was especially true in the Great Plains and the southern Cotton Belt, where farm families continued to face declining crop prices, high railroad and warehouse fees, tight credit, tenancy, and foreclosures. In 1892, the movement found a new base in the Populist (or People’s) Party, a third party that would galvanize millions of Americans and bring the crusade against Wall Street to the center stage of the nation’s politics.
Knit together by newspapers, pamphlets, and roving orators who crisscrossed rural counties, Populism spoke to the grievances and fears of farmers, laborers, and small businesspeople who believed that they were victimized by powerful bankers and investors based in the urban and financially ascendant Northeast, and by their lackeys among the politicians of both major parties. Populists carried forward the banner of an expanding currency, echoing the Greenbackers in demands for a more “elastic” money that would end the tyranny of gold and provide easy credit and higher crop prices for the ordinary westerners and southerners who needed them. Increasingly, the movement attracted “silverites”—those who believed that an expanded bimetallic currency of silver and gold, rather than paper greenbacks, would bring prosperity for the common man. Silver advocates gained a national audience after 1893, when yet another financial crisis beginning on Wall Street led to a crushing four-year depression.
The Populists believed that New York City, controlled by a small handful of despotic bankers, had displaced Washington, D.C., as the nation’s capital. “The Government itself lies prone in the dust with the iron heel of Wall Street upon its neck,” declared Tom Watson of Georgia, the Populist candidate for vice president in 1896. Comparing the gold-obsessed bankers to their Tory predecessors during the American Revolution, William “Coin” Harvey, a leading Populist writer, charged in 1894 that “the business men of New York passed strong resolutions against the Declaration of Independence in 1776, and they are passing strong resolutions against an American policy now.” Mary E. Lease, the Kansas Populist orator, further claimed that this financial aristocracy controlled the fate of the country. “A few men in New York may meet at a wine supper and decree a reduction of wages for a million men, thus inviting a strike that might paralyze the industries of the whole nation, precipitating riots that might give a pretext for calling out national troops” to crush the desperate strikers. At the ballot box, as in their publications, Populists called on the people to reduce the power of Wall Street, expand the currency, and restore the republic.9

The War of Wealth, ca. 1895. Lithograph (303/10 × 402/10 in). Published by The Strobridge Lithographing Co., Cincinnati and New York.
Library of Congress, Prints and Photographs Division
Charles Dazey’s melodrama The War of Wealth, staged in New York in 1896, pitted a heroic and “manly” cashier against a villainous junior bank partner, who stole from the bank to cover his losses in speculation. A reviewer noted that the villain was roundly hissed by the audience. Concerns over the morality of banking penetrated both popular culture and politics during the depression of the mid-1890s.
While a radical egalitarian impulse ran through Populism, prompting its spokesmen to call for low-interest government loans to farmers, a federal takeover of railroads and telegraph lines for public benefit, the creation of savings banks in post offices, and the abolition of commodity and stock exchanges, the movement’s obsession with conspiracy theories led many Populists to embrace less liberal ideas. According to Populist pamphleteers, behind Wall Street lay the power of London banks, especially the Bank of England, which dictated a gold-based currency in order to enslave Americans to British greed. Greenbacks and/or silver would bring a truly patriotic currency, free of the control and taint of foreigners. Just as sinister, Populists saw the influence of Jews in every financial measure they hated. August Belmont, the German-born Jew who had been chairman of the Democratic National Committee in New York and funded a number of “sound money” publications and political candidates, became a special target of Populist wrath due to his role as American agent for the Rothschild bank of London. The fact that the Rothschilds and other European investment bankers bought large blocks of U.S. government bonds, usually through Wall Street banking houses, allegedly gave them an ominous influence over federal policies. Populist writers and speakers repeatedly warned of the devious power of “Wall Street, and the Jews of Europe,” or “Jewish bankers and British gold.” The aim of “Shylock,” pamphleteer Sarah Emery contended, was “to rob the people through exorbitant rates of interest.”10
Wall Street Strikes Back
Ironically, some of Wall Street’s most powerful bankers shared anti-Semitic views (though little else) with the Populists. Uncomfortable with the postwar rise of German Jewish private banking firms such as Kuhn, Loeb and J. & W. Seligman, bankers of British Protestant descent increasingly excluded Jews from any share in the city’s elite social and cultural life. J. P. Morgan complained privately that his firm and Baring Brothers were the only two remaining banking firms “composed of white men in New York”—meaning that Jacob Schiff, James Speyer, and other German Jewish rivals were not white, and therefore racially and morally inferior. For being “Israelites,” the family of banker Joseph Seligman in 1877 was denied a suite at a posh hotel in Saratoga Springs, New York, frequented by Manhattan’s business class. The incident inaugurated an era of elite anti-Semitism that kept Jewish financiers out of New York’s leading clubs and resorts. Yet the relationship between Protestants and Jews on Wall Street was also more complex. Repeatedly, Morgan invited Kuhn, Loeb into the large bond-issuing syndicates the firm organized, thereby admitting its rival as a collaborator. Most “Yankee” bankers treated Jews with a modicum of civility during business negotiations, while keeping them at a distance after hours.11

“Bark up lively, my hungry pups!…” Published in Southern Mercury, May 21, 1896.
From Populist Cartoons: An Illustrated History of the Third-Party Movement of the 1890s by Worth Robert Miller (Kirksville, MO: Truman State University Press, 2011)
This cartoon from a Dallas, Texas newspaper illustrates a central Populist tenet: that the “Gold Syndicate” of Wall Street financiers (here symbolized by a stereotypically Jewish banker) bribed and controlled the candidates of both the Republican and “Gold Democrat” parties, thereby corrupting the nation’s politics.
Despite their bigotry, Morgan and other gentile bankers also worked with Jews in campaigns against the common “soft money” enemy. New York financiers responded to the crusades of Greenbackers and silver advocates with energetic counterattacks. In 1877, a delegation including J. P. Morgan, Joseph Seligman, and the First National Bank’s Francis O. French traveled to Washington to lobby the Senate against enacting “dangerous” inflationary laws; George Coe of the American Exchange Bank, private banker Levi P. Morton, and August Belmont also helped mobilize pro-gold businessmen to petition Congress. In the 1890s, bankers James Stillman and James Speyer were active in the New York Reform Club, an organization dedicated to sponsoring pamphlets, speakers, and mass meetings nationwide in support of “honest money” (gold) against the silver activists.
The 1896 Republican presidential campaign against William Jennings Bryan similarly required widespread support from New York’s banking community. When the Democratic and Populist parties both chose Nebraska’s pro-silver Bryan as their candidate, Republicans and alienated “Gold Democrats” across the country looked to Manhattan for aid in electing William McKinley, “the Advance Agent of Prosperity.” Bankers played a major role in raising money from the business community to defeat Bryan, a man many saw as a wild-eyed radical who would bring “Populistic communism … and anarchism” to the White House. Pressed into service by Mark Hanna, McKinley’s campaign manager, numerous New York bankers and industrialists, including railroad magnate James J. Hill and the National City Bank’s William Rockefeller, raised $3 million of the then-staggering total of $3.5 million that flowed into the Republican campaign chest. Hill and Hanna literally spent five days on Wall Street going from office to office, soliciting funds. Hanna’s systematic canvassing of bankers and corporate leaders helped to inaugurate modern campaign finance in America. It also proved highly effective in promoting McKinley’s candidacy.12
Along with business opposition, Bryan’s inability to secure widespread labor or urban support for his campaign pitting “The People” against “Wall Street” doomed the Populist crusade to failure; the movement’s antiurban and antiforeign biases held little appeal in the nation’s burgeoning immigrant cities. Economic changes undercut a revival of rural insurgency thereafter. In the late 1890s, an expanding demand for food in American cities and European markets—two traditional sources of corruption in Populist thinking—raised crop prices and launched two decades of prosperity for farmers. An upsurge in the number of state-chartered banks and revised rules that made it easier to open National Banks in smaller cities and towns increased the availability of bank credit and equalized interest rates across the country. Gold rushes in Australia, Canada, and Alaska increased the world supply of the metal, amplifying the nation’s circulating currency without dramatic greenback or silver expansion. Yet although Populism died as a movement, much of its moral outrage remained, carried forward by socialists, labor unionists, and reformers who had joined Populists in calls for the regulation or even overthrow of concentrated finance capitalism. In the 20th century, conflict would resume over the threats to opportunity, equality, and democracy that many Americans still saw when they looked in the direction of Lower Manhattan. The locus of dissent, however, shifted from farmers’ halls to urban magazine offices, middle-class living rooms, and legislative hearings.

Prosperity at home, prestige abroad, ca. 1895–1900. Lithograph. Published by Northwestern Litho. Co., Milwaukee, Wisconsin.
Library of Congress, Prints and Photographs Division
Republican William McKinley (standing here on a gold coin labeled “Sound Money”) pledged to maintain the gold standard against the Populist and “Silver Democrat” assault. Although printed in Milwaukee, this campaign poster exemplifies the view of many New York bankers and voters that a gold currency actually united northern urban businessmen and workers against agrarian radicals.
Progressive Reform
“We do not wish to destroy corporations, but we do wish to make them subserve the public good.” So spoke Republican President Theodore Roosevelt to a Cincinnati audience in 1902, signaling a new, “progressive” era in American politics that would cast banks in a new role in the national dialogue. The era had been effectively inaugurated in 1898, when the United States Industrial Commission, a body appointed by Congress to assess recent economic developments, warned that investment bankers and brokers were rewarding themselves with questionably large fees when they organized corporate mergers for tin plate manufacturers, silverware producers, and other industrial concerns. Under Roosevelt, the White House also scrutinized business consolidations. In 1902, Roosevelt’s Justice Department launched a lawsuit against the Northern Securities Company, a railroad conglomerate put together by New York financiers J. P. Morgan, James J. Hill, Jacob Schiff, and E. H. Harriman. The president concurred with the railroad’s critics, who saw it as an illicit monopoly that singlehandedly controlled much of the rail traffic in the Midwest, to the detriment of customers and shippers. In 1904, the Supreme Court agreed that the company violated the Sherman Antitrust Act (1890), which prohibited anticompetitive practices by American businesses, and the Northern Securities Company was dissolved. Progressive reformers were reacting to a great wave of industrial mergers in the late 1890s and early 1900s, many of them arranged by New York bankers. While Roosevelt himself repeatedly turned to Wall Street bankers, especially J. P. Morgan, to help mediate industrial disputes and overcome financial crises, “trust busting” had moved to the forefront of political ferment in Washington and New York.13
As the nation’s media capital, New York was now the incubator as well as the target of banking controversy. The publishers and editors of mass-circulation magazines like McClure’s, Collier’s, and Everybody’s dispatched reporters to expose corruption and abuses of power wherever they found them—in monopolistic corporations like the Standard Oil Company, in Tammany Hall and other urban political machines, even in the U.S. Senate. Headquartered in Manhattan, these “muckraking” magazines often had offices only a few blocks from the subjects of their investigations.
Wall Street’s turn came in 1904–05, when Everybody’s Magazine—a periodical of general interest for middle-class readers—ran a series of articles in 1899 entitled “Frenzied Finance” by Thomas Lawson, a Boston stockbroker with inside information on the creation of the large Amalgamated Copper Mining Company—the “Copper Trust.” Lawson detailed how the merger of copper companies had been orchestrated by the National City Bank, managed by James Stillman and his brother-in-law William Rockefeller (brother of Standard Oil magnate John D. Rockefeller). Lawson also asserted that this “‘Standard Oil’ bank,” as he called it, played a dominant and hidden role in the city’s booming insurance industry. He painted a picture of wealthy New York-based life insurance firms—New York Life, Equitable, and Mutual Life—linked to financial houses and industrial corporations by bankers who sat on the boards of all the intertwined companies, unbeknownst to policy holders, many shareholders, and the general public. Lawson charged that large banks like National City had the power to invest the money of insurance policy holders and investors as they chose; the results were personal windfalls for bankers and insurance executives, financial disaster for unknowing shareholders, and a concentration of power in the hands of a small number of banking tycoons who pulled the strings of the nation’s largest companies. Lawson intended his revelations to restore accountability and fairness to big business. “Every scoundrel with a mask, dark-lantern, and suspicious-looking bag will stand out so clearly that he cannot escape the consequences of his past deeds,” he proclaimed.14
Lawson’s sensational articles alarmed middle-class readers, who believed hidden speculation jeopardized the security of vulnerable policy holders, despite the avowals of company heads that bank-directed investments actually guaranteed payments on policies. “Frenzied Finance” prompted calls for governmental investigation. By mid-1905, New York State’s Superintendent of Insurance was advocating “the elimination of Wall Street control” over the industry. The ensuing Armstrong Committee inquiry in the New York State legislature in 1905-06 followed up on Lawson’s charges. The committee’s counsel, Manhattan lawyer Charles Evans Hughes, examined an array of witnesses from New York’s business community in an effort to determine what role commercial and investment bankers played in controlling insurance company investments, and to what extent they were colluding—creating a conflict of interest—by selling corporate stocks and bonds to themselves in their role as directors of insurance companies.15

In the wake of the 1907 Wall Street panic and the unrelenting consolidation of large corporations, scrutiny of New York banks shifted from Albany to Washington.

The inquiry revealed the extent to which American big business and big banks now conducted their business with each other in the same set of Wall Street and Midtown boardrooms. George W. Perkins, vice president of New York Life and a Morgan partner, meant to reassure the Armstrong Committee when he described his multiple roles: “Mr. Chairman … I know when a transaction comes to me, whether it is in J. P. Morgan & Company, or the New York Life or the Steel Corporation, or whatever it may be, I take up that question and dispose of it as I see my duty.” Such comments, which revealed the concentrated power hidden from the public, alarmed many New Yorkers who followed the investigation in newspapers and magazines. The Armstrong Committee concluded that life insurance companies were investing millions of dollars of their funds in corporate securities sold by the investment bankers sitting on their boards. To end the speculative risk to policy holders and the conflict of interest such investments represented, the New York State legislature passed laws in 1906 prohibiting life insurance companies from buying corporate stocks, barring them from taking part in syndicates organized by bankers to underwrite new corporate securities, and preventing insurance executives from personally investing in and profiting from company transactions. By 1908, 19 other states had also enacted “Armstrong” laws.16

Harris & Ewing, Pujo Committee, 1912.
Library of Congress, Prints and Photographs Division
Members of the Pujo Committee, including Chairman Arsene Pujo (fifth from left) and counsel Samuel Untermyer (seated far right), pose during their hearings on the “Money Trust.”
The Pujo Committee
In the wake of the 1907 Wall Street panic and the unrelenting consolidation of large corporations, scrutiny of New York banks shifted from Albany to Washington. In 1912, a House subcommittee chaired by Louisiana Democrat Arsene Pujo called an array of star witnesses, including J. P. Morgan himself, Jacob Schiff of Kuhn, Loeb, George F. Baker of the First National Bank, and others, in an effort to determine whether a “Money Trust” controlled American finance in ways that limited opportunity and competition. It was obvious that when investment banking houses and their affiliated commercial banks and trust companies created large syndicates to sell or buy new issues of stocks and bonds for railroads, utilities, or manufacturers, they put tens or even hundreds of millions of dollars in motion. The committee’s majority concluded that an “inner group” of banks—J. P. Morgan, First National Bank, National City Bank, Kuhn, Loeb, and two Boston banking firms, Lee, Higginson and Kidder, Peabody—collaborated to manage the access of corporate clients to capital. They thereby controlled the flow of credit to American industry and in the process kept the rates and fees the banks charged their clients at an artificially inflated level. The presence of investment bankers on the boards of dozens of corporations for whom they raised capital upset the Pujo Committee as much as it had the New York State investigators of life insurance companies six years before. By dominating scores of other banks, trust companies, railroads, public utilities, manufacturing corporations, and the money they accumulated, a small number of bankers mostly headquartered on Wall Street appeared to the critics to have all but total control over access to capital and credit. “The powerful grip of these gentlemen is upon the throttle that controls the wheels of credit and upon their signal those wheels will turn or stop,” alleged the committee’s majority report.17
Other aspects of Wall Street banking also struck Pujo investigators as troubling signs of the concentration of financial power. For example, as private partnerships, investment houses were legally immune from routine government inspection, unlike state-chartered commercial and savings banks or federally incorporated National Banks. The resulting secrecy of investment banks like Morgan and Kuhn, Loeb, and the unwillingness or inability of their partners to divulge the details of specific relationships and transactions, disturbed congressmen seeking what we would today call transparency. Another worrisome aspect of Wall Street practice was the fact that much of the capital used by investment banks consisted of “other people’s money” in the form of multimillion-dollar sums deposited in the banks by the corporations whose bonds and stocks the banks issued. Corporation shareholders thus had neither control over nor knowledge of how their investments were being used by bankers. The committee majority’s final report affirmed that there was, indeed, a “Money Trust” that “resulted in great and rapidly growing concentration of the control of money and credit in the hands of these few men.”18
The Pujo Committee devised and recommended some creative proposals for diluting the power of the Money Trust, albeit through indirect means. Samuel Untermyer, the committee’s legal counsel, believed that this could be done by imposing state and federal supervision on the New York Stock Exchange, through which the banks marketed securities; prohibiting National Banks from underwriting and selling stocks and bonds; and requiring interstate corporations to use multiple banks to market their securities, thus avoiding exclusive reliance on one powerful banking house and the syndicate of compliant banks it assembled to raise capital. Such measures would not only prevent monopoly but also restore the transparency that Americans needed to understand what was happening to finance and industry. “Publicity is justly commended as a remedy for social and industrial diseases,” asserted the lawyer Louis D. Brandeis, a key advisor to the new Democratic president, Woodrow Wilson, and author of “Other People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It,” a series of scathing articles in Harper’s Weekly in 1913–14. “Sunlight is said to be the best of disinfectants; electric light the most efficient policeman.” A disgruntled J. P. Morgan echoed his adversary: “The time is coming when all business will have to be done with glass pockets.” Shortly after Morgan’s death in 1913, his son and successor, Jack (J. P. Morgan, Jr.), along with four of his senior partners, voluntarily resigned from the boards of dozens of corporations, in his words, to appease “public feeling” aroused against J. P. Morgan and Company by the Pujo Committee “and the press generally.”19

Tearsheet from “Serve One Master Only” by Louis D. Brandeis. Published by Harper’s Weekly, December 13, 1913.
Museum of American Finance, New York City
This magazine article was one of ten that Louis Brandeis penned for Harper’s Weekly between November 1913 and January 1914, which were immediately compiled into the book Other People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It. The series marked the climax of progressive-era journalistic scrutiny of American banking. The lawyer-reformer took Wall Street investment banks to task for imposing the “curse of bigness” on American business and allegedly curtailing competition. President Wilson appointed Brandeis to the U.S. Supreme Court in 1916.
Measures enacted in response to the Pujo report, most notably the Clayton Antitrust Act passed by Congress in 1914 with Wilson’s support, left much to be desired in the eyes of reformers. As originally conceived, the Clayton Act was supposed to ban interlocking corporate directorates and shareholdings and permit the federal government to launch aggressive prosecutions of individuals and corporations for breaking the law, with fines and prison sentences as penalties. These regulations, Brandeis and others concluded, would break up the hidden concentrations of power devised by bankers and their corporate clients and help restore a marketplace where smaller, newer economic units—both banks and industrial concerns—could compete and distribute opportunity and wealth in a far fairer and democratic way. But after being watered down by the Senate Judiciary Committee, the final draft actually made prosecutions difficult by requiring the government to prove that bankers had substantially lessened competition when they sat on the boards of multiple corporations or controlled securities in an array of interlocking banks and companies. As one disappointed senator put it, the Clayton Act originally “was a raging lion with a mouth full of teeth. It has degenerated into a tabby cat with soft gums, a plaintive mew, and an anaemic appearance.” Moreover, President Wilson himself, forced to balance the conflicting desires of progressives and financial conservatives in Congress and in his own Democratic Party, appointed conservatives to the new Federal Trade Commission established in 1914, men largely uninterested in limiting big banks and corporations. Uneasy about censuring or alienating businessmen who could help the national economy recover from an ongoing recession, Wilson ultimately drew back from the radical implications of his own Jeffersonian rhetoric about the dangers posed by concentrated bigness. Additionally, no securities market regulation—a lynchpin in Untermyer’s plan—passed Congress. Nor would Republican Presidents Harding, Coolidge, or Hoover, enthusiastic champions of the efficiency and prosperity ostensibly promoted by unfettered business, make regulation of big banks or corporations a federal priority during the 1920s.20
Grilling the “Money Trusters”
As for New York’s financiers, they bristled at the charges of the muckrakers and congressional inquiries. To reformers, the “curse of bigness” was that it allowed bankers and corporations to be inefficient since they did not have to face the rigors of competition. Bankers like J. P. Morgan believed just the opposite: that ruinous cutthroat competition between rival railroads, steel mills, and steamship lines was the essence of inefficiency and economic disaster, impoverishing investors and throwing employees out of work as price and rate cuts led profits to plunge. Investment bankers were performing a public service by consolidating industries that flourished and spurred economic growth. Morgan partner George W. Perkins told the Armstrong Committee in 1906 that “the old idea that we were raised under, that competition is the life of trade, is exploded. Competition is no longer the life of trade, it is co-operation.” At the same time, bankers denied that they were monopolists who conspired to hike their fees and limit their corporate clients’ freedom of choice. When Samuel Untermyer grilled the 76-year-old J. P. Morgan, the financial “titan” defended large banking syndicates while denying that he was the master puppeteer of the American economy:

“The old idea that we were raised under, that competition is the life of trade, is exploded.”
George W. Perkins
Mr. Morgan: … Without … control you cannot do anything.
Mr. Untermyer: Well, I guess that is right. Is that the reason you want to control everything?
Mr. Morgan: I want to control nothing.
Mr. Untermyer: What you mean is that there is no way one man can get it all?
Mr. Morgan: Or any of it … or control of it.
Mr. Untermyer: He can make a try at it?
Mr. Morgan: No, sir; he cannot. He may have all the money in Christendom, but he cannot do it.21
Similarly, though Jacob Schiff used his testimony to state that “monopolies are odious,” he defended the legitimacy of Wall Street banking, asserting that syndicate participation did not undermine “the sense of honor” held dear by “New York bank presidents or trust company presidents.” Like Morgan, Schiff jousted with Untermyer:
George Leonidas Leslie and the Golden Age of Heists
In his lifetime, George Leonidas Leslie was known in New York’s high society as George Howard, a wealthy, well-educated bibliophile and a fixture at New York’s libraries, theaters, and dinner parties. But to criminals across the country, Leslie was the greatest bank robber who ever lived. Earlier thieves had stolen from the city’s banks—making off, for example, with $37,810 in bank notes from the Bank of the State of New-York on Wall Street in 1853, and five bags containing $25,000 in gold coins from the Merchants’ Bank in 1855. But Leslie elevated bank robbery to an art form. Combining technical and financial expertise with painstaking attention to detail, he planned and executed dozens of bank robberies between his arrival in New York in 1869 and his murder nine years later.
Leslie moved seamlessly between high society and the criminal underworld. Several years after moving to New York from Cincinnati with a degree in architecture, the debonair young man had purchased an elegant home on Fulton Street. Leslie befriended influential New Yorkers such as financier “Jubilee Jim” Fisk, and he reportedly carried on an affair with Fisk’s equally famous mistress, Josie Mansfield. Leslie also forged a close relationship with Marm Mandelbaum, New York’s leading “fence,” or distributor of stolen goods. At the dinner parties Mandelbaum threw in her lavish apartment on Clinton Street, behind what appeared to be a dry goods store, Leslie rubbed elbows with infamous criminals like “Shang” Draper and “Red” Leary, and the corrupt businessmen, lawyers, and politicians who protected them. These society connections proved invaluable to his career as a bank robber.
“Bank Burglars Outfit,” c. 1887.
Published in Recollections of a New York Chief of Police, by George W. Walling (New York: Caxton Book Concern, 1887)
Leslie’s first major heist, the 1869 robbery of Ocean National Bank on Greenwich Street in Manhattan, set the standard for his career, demonstrating his social skills, his architect’s eye for detail, and his financial literacy. Leslie first used his connections to convince Ocean National’s management to hire one of his accomplices as a janitor, gaining him access to the bank. On his first break-in, Leslie drilled a small hole in the safe’s lock and slid in his “little joker,” a strip of metal he had designed, which, left inside the lock, would record the positions of the tumblers when the safe was opened the next morning. When he and his gang broke in a second time, the little joker, and the combination, would be waiting for them. Leslie also rented a room in the bank’s basement, directly below the vault, where he installed a wooden cabinet with a complete set of bank robber’s tools, including equipment to drill up through the floor.
Leslie’s genius didn’t end with getting into the bank—he was also painstakingly careful about what came out. It was as if, in the words of New York Police Chief George Walling, “the robbers had cherished just a little contempt for ‘filthy lucre,’ so much had they left scattered on the floor,” including “bags of gold and nickel coins, bundles of checks, bonds, notes … all mixed up in a hopeless confusion.” Although the thieves made off with nearly $800,000 in cash, checks, and jewelry, an incredible sum of money for the time, they left nearly $2 million on the floor of Ocean National’s vault. But there was nothing confused about what Leslie had instructed his men to take—heavy gold would slow them down, and securities were useless to a thief, since they usually had the name of their rightful owner printed on them. Arguably, one of Leslie’s most important advantages in the art of bank robbery was his own financial literacy.22
The 1878 heist of the Manhattan Savings Institution on Broadway at Bleecker Street would have been Leslie’s crowning achievement—if he had seen it through. His plan used many of the techniques developed for the robbery of Ocean National Bank, perfected over a decade of practice. In the months before the robbery, Leslie broke into the bank three times with the help of night watchman Pat Shevlin, cracking the safe’s combination and drawing up floor plans.
Leslie used this information to construct a full-size replica of the bank’s vault in a warehouse owned by Marm Mandelbaum, and he rehearsed his handpicked team of crack thieves until every detail of the operation went like clockwork. But on June 4, 1878, Leslie was found dead, his handsomely dressed, partly decomposed body discovered in a sparsely populated corner of Yonkers.
Leslie’s accomplices went forward with the Manhattan Savings Institution robbery, bereft of his expertise. Armed with the vault combination and Leslie’s carefully rehearsed plan, his team, now under Shang Draper’s leadership, walked off with nearly $3 million. According to the police, it was “the ‘cleanest job’ that ever came under their notice.” But the sensational newspaper headlines about the “great bank robbery” were misleading. In fact, the vast majority of the haul was worthless registered securities. Only the rightful owner could cash them, so the bank simply had them reprinted. Draper left almost all of the bank’s considerable cash in the vault—a mistake George Leslie would never have made.23
With so little profit to show for their efforts, the gang was unable to pay the $250,000 they had promised to Pat Shevlin, their inside man. Embittered, Shevlin confessed to the police, and within a year the perpetrators were in jail. Ironically, although Leslie’s name will always be associated with the Great Bank Robbery of 1878, this cunning robber was already dead and buried before his killers committed the most audacious crime he ever planned. Had Leslie been alive, it is unlikely he would have been caught.
—Bernard J. Lillis

Art Young, cartoon of J. P. Morgan from The Masses, February 1913.
The Modernist Journals Project, Brown University and The University of Tulsa
Cartoonist Art Young, a member of the Socialist Party, used one of J. P. Morgan’s statements during his Pujo Committee testimony—“I like a little competition”—to comment sardonically on the banker’s role in the so-called “Money Trust.” The cartoon appeared in The Masses, a magazine published in the 1910s by Greenwich Village intellectuals and radicals.
Mr. Untermyer: Then, your idea is that the law should not regulate these things at all, but should depend upon these self-respecting gentlemen to regulate themselves? Is that it?
Mr. Schiff: I think the less law in such instances the better.… I think there should be a proper supervision, but you can crush the life out of a bank by too much law, and you can make it impossible for them to do the functions for which they exist.24
In a letter to the committee, Morgan conceded that New York City had become the nation’s financial capital, but he argued that this was the result of natural “economic laws which in every country create some one city as the great financial centre,” rather than proof of a Wall Street conspiracy to aggrandize all wealth and power. Morgan partners, Schiff, and other private bankers repeatedly cited their personal character and integrity as gentlemen and businessmen as the best proof that the Pujo charges were false and misleading.25
Financiers fought back actively against the reformers. A new trade association, the Investment Bankers Association of America (IBA, 1912), representing 373 investment firms in New York, Chicago, and 40 other cities, publicly denounced both the Pujo majority report and Brandeis’s Harper’s articles. The IBA also lobbied state legislatures to modify “Blue Sky laws,” a series of statutes first enacted by several states between 1911 and 1916 to regulate the advertising and sale of securities. The laws, meant to protect ordinary consumers from being sold fraudulent, worthless, or misrepresented stocks and bonds by brokers and bankers, were so named because of the notion that security salesmen would try to sell ignorant buyers the “blue sky” itself if they could get away with it. In response, the New York-based Banker’s Magazine contested the idea of protecting consumers in 1912 by arguing that “there is little ground for government intervention to save the fool and the knave [i.e., the stock or bond buyer] from the consequences of his own folly and knavery.” Nevertheless, Blue Sky laws were ruled constitutional by the U.S. Supreme Court in 1917 and by 1933, had been enacted in all the 48 states except Nevada. New York’s Martin Act, passed in 1921, came to be considered one of the most sweeping and aggressive of these anti-financial fraud laws. Yet, while the state laws protected consumers against unscrupulous sales practices, they reduced banking consolidation no more effectively than did the Clayton Act. One lasting effect, however, was to teach bankers in New York and elsewhere that in a new world of mass journalism, insurgent politics, advertising, and public relations, financiers had to embrace tactics (associations, speeches, circulars, periodicals, op-ed articles, lobbying campaigns) to challenge the arguments of reformers and convince consumers, voters, readers, and officeholders of the integrity, safety, and necessity of the nation’s large banks.26
Historians, most notably Vincent P. Carosso, have largely agreed with the bankers concerning the nonexistence of an effective “Money Trust.” Rather than colluding to keep corporations from seeking lower fees or better services, Wall Street banks competed for clients, even though Jacob Schiff and other Pujo witnesses admitted that they valued stability and long-term relationships with their corporate clients. The formation of bond- or stock-issuing syndicates by Morgan or Kuhn, Loeb was a constantly shifting process involving hundreds of banks and brokerages across the country, even if the most important players were in New York. The fact that bankers sat on numerous corporation boards, moreover, did not mean that they held an iron grip on the policies and decisions of those companies; managers and shareholders often welcomed their expertise, advice, and reputations as corporate assets.
And yet, if progressives exaggerated the monopolistic grip that Wall Street banks held on the American economy, the grievances they aired—the power and secrecy of large corporations; the ability of those corporations to determine labor conditions, wages, and consumer prices; bank and business influence in politics and government—struck a deep chord among millions of Americans. New York bankers had created a new economy, daunting in the sheer scale and consolidation of its resources and influence. “There is a close and well-defined ‘community of interest’ and understanding among the men who dominate the financial destinies of our country and who wield fabulous power over the fortunes of others,” Samuel Untermyer had claimed in a 1911 speech at Manhattan’s West Side YMCA. His charge continued to resonate among ordinary Americans in New York and across the country.27
Creating the Federal Reserve
Meanwhile, Wall Street bankers themselves were acting to bring momentous change by creating the era’s most lasting financial innovation, the Federal Reserve System. As much as they profited from the National Banking System set up during the Civil War, many bankers were troubled by the way the system concentrated deposit reserves in New York, which triggered recurring panics and depressions when western and southern banks tightened credit on Wall Street by calling back their reserves. The nation had lacked anything akin to a central bank—a public or private institution that performed the federal government’s financial and monetary duties—since the demise of the Second Bank of the United States in 1836. But after the Panic of 1907, numerous bankers, academics, and legislators embraced the idea of a centralized institution that might stabilize and regulate the flow of currency so as to eliminate extreme fluctuations in interest rates and the availability of money. Such an entity could prevent or at least soften economic booms and busts, while serving as a “bank of last resort” to which other banks could turn for loans in times of crisis.

Frank A. Nankivell, “The Central Bank,” from Puck, February 2, 1910. Published by Keppler and Schwarzmann, New York.
Library of Congress, Prints and Photographs Division
This cartoon uses the image of a grasping J. P. Morgan to suggest that a “Central Bank”—in the guise of early plans for a Federal Reserve System—might not be able to neutralize or offset Wall Street’s “Money Power.”
In November 1910, Republican Senator Nelson Aldrich of Rhode Island, chairman of the National Monetary Commission established after the 1907 panic, convened a meeting of the nation’s leading bankers at an exclusive resort on Jekyll Island, Georgia. Aldrich invited Assistant Treasury Secretary A. Piatt Andrew; Paul Warburg of Kuhn, Loeb; Frank Vanderlip of National City Bank; Morgan representatives Henry Davison and Benjamin Strong, Jr.; and Charles Norton of the First National Bank of New York to hammer out a plan to remedy the shortcomings of the National Banking System. According to one estimate, the assembled New Yorkers represented about one-quarter of the world’s wealth at the time. Aldrich insisted on the utmost secrecy for the meeting, and the bankers left New York via a Jersey City train station, posing as duck hunters, a ruse that did not fool snooping reporters. “Picture a party of the nation’s greatest bankers stealing out of New York on a private railroad car under cover of darkness,” a journalist later recalled, “… sneaking onto an island deserted by all but a few servants” in order to shield from public view “this strangest, most secret expedition in the history of American finance.” Aldrich meant the privacy to allow the bankers to debate different approaches to the politically controversial issue of a central bank. Its lasting impact was to prompt speculations by generations of conspiracy theorists that the Federal Reserve was a Wall Street plot to manipulate the economy.28
The result of the Jekyll Island conference and Aldrich’s National Monetary Commission studies was a series of recommendations that shaped the Federal Reserve Act. After much debate and disagreement both inside and outside Congress, planners and legislators sought to steer a middle course between the criticisms of ex-Populists, westerners, and southerners who feared a system empowering the big banks of the Northeast, and the reservations of urban bankers alarmed by potential government control of American finance. When passed by Congress with Wilson’s support in 1913, the act established 12 districts across the country, each with a Federal Reserve Bank. All National Banks were legally required to become members by buying stock and depositing reserves in their district’s “Fed” bank. State-chartered banks were invited to join under similar conditions. A Federal Reserve Board of Governors in Washington—consisting of the Treasury Secretary, the Comptroller of the Currency, and five presidential appointees—controlled the system. But the act sought to defuse fears of concentrated power by giving considerable decision-making autonomy to the 12 Federal Reserve Banks, each of whose nine-person boards balanced Washington appointees with directors elected by local member banks, only three of whom could be bankers. Three of the board members in each of the 12 districts would be chosen from among local businessmen and civic-minded citizens who, presumably, would provide a popular and democratic counterbalance keeping bankers from monopolizing Fed policy. This initial diffusion of power was partly a political concession to fears of Wall Street control, a lasting if indirect legacy of Greenbackism, Populism, and progressive reform.

The Federal Reserve System created a flexible national money reserve that seemed to remove the threat of depleted bank vaults… triggering nationwide panics and depressions.

To prevent future financial panics, the Federal Reserve needed ways to provide cash reserves so that when worried depositors sought to cash checks and remove money from their bank accounts, they would receive it, thereby calming the jittery public and preventing mass stampedes on banks. (See “Panic!”, page 63.) Toward this end, the Fed used the reserve deposits of its members as a fund to lend to banks under pressure from depositors and customers. Such banks could use their assets (for example, designated types of securities and IOUs from commercial debtors) as collateral, borrowing from the Fed at an interest rate set by Fed officers. Thus the borrowing banks would have ample cash on hand to quell anxieties, while the Fed could regulate the national flow of capital—and guard against either inflation or recession—by raising or lowering the interest rate it charged for loans. While the nation remained on the gold standard and National Bank Notes were not fully discontinued and retired by the U.S. Treasury until 1935, the Fed also put a new national paper currency, Federal Reserve Notes, into circulation through its loans to banks. It remains our paper money today.
New Yorkers played a seminal role in the early years of the Federal Reserve System. Wilson asked the German-born Paul Warburg of Kuhn, Loeb, one of the system’s most important intellectual architects, to join the Federal Reserve Board of Governors in Washington. A surprised Warburg commented, “I did not think the President would be at all likely to submit the name of a man associated with one of the leading Wall Street firms.” Indeed, Warburg’s nomination prompted a resurgence of Populist anger; Congressman Joe Eagle of Texas declared that he would oppose the appointment because Warburg was “a Jew, a German, a banker and an alien.” Yet the nomination helped to reassure many bankers who were as suspicious of government intervention as old Populists were of Wall Street machinations. The Senate confirmed Warburg, and he served on the board until 1918.29
When it was fully implemented in 1914, the Federal Reserve System created a flexible national money reserve that seemed to remove the threat of depleted bank vaults—especially New York City’s—triggering nationwide panics and depressions. During World War I, the Fed’s interest-rate policies helped to expand the nation’s money supply to meet wartime needs; however, the Fed later inadvertently helped to exacerbate postwar inflation and recession. Not until the 1920s did Fed authorities, most notably the confident Benjamin Strong, Jr.—Jekyll Island conferee, former vice president of the Morgan-controlled Banker’s Trust of New York, and now Governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York—realize that there was another efficient way to regulate the nation’s money flow. By buying and selling securities—especially U.S. government notes—on a mass scale, the Fed could swell or shrink the commercial bank accounts of investors, thus regulating the amount of money in bank reserves across the country so as to ensure stability and liquidity. If the Fed believed that available money was growing too scarce, it could buy large amounts of bonds on the open market, leading the sellers to deposit Fed payments in their banks and thus expanding available capital for loans, payments, and cash. If the Fed feared that too much money in circulation was producing inflation, it could sell bonds, absorbing money from the buyers and removing it from their commercial bank accounts and the economy.

Wurts Bros., Federal Reserve Bank, Nassau Street and Maiden Lane, 1924.
Museum of the City of New York, X2010.7.1.11046
These “open market operations” would become a central regulatory tool of the Federal Reserve, a role they still play today. Under Strong, open market operations also augmented the power of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which bought and sold large quantities of government paper in order to affect the balances held in New York’s dominant commercial banks. Due to its special relationship to the nation’s money market a few blocks away in the banks of Wall Street, the New York Fed had from the start been the “first among equals” of the 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks. Until his death in 1928, Strong bickered almost continually with the Federal Reserve Board in Washington, and with other regional Federal Banks, over policy and control. But although the system’s functions evolved and became more centralized in Washington over the decades, New York’s primacy was assumed from the beginning. In the years to come, it would be from the Trading Desk at 33 Liberty Street in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York that the nation’s day-to-day monetary policy would be executed, following directives from the system’s Washington-based Federal Open Market Committee to buy and sell U.S. Treasury notes in the open market.
The Great War and After
While the Federal Reserve System was getting under way in 1914, the outbreak of World War I led to a new era of turbulence and agitation on Wall Street and throughout the nation. With Populists marginalized and progressives either silenced or converted to the war effort, leftists became the most visible critics of Wall Street and plutocracy. For socialists and anarchists, American loans to the warring European nations amounting to hundreds of millions of dollars—together with the profits pouring into the pockets of munitions makers, war contractors, shareholders, and bankers—proved that the war was primarily an opportunity for capitalists to cash in on misery and bloodshed. Socialist Morris Hillquit, who proclaimed the war “a cold-blooded butchery” serving “the ruling classes of the warring nations,” failed in his 1917 New York City mayoral bid, but he did garner 142,000 votes. Such dissent, however, increasingly invited suppression by federal agents and private vigilantes. The New York Times lambasted “half-baked disciples of socialism, internationalists, pro-Germanists” who didn’t buy or “believe in Liberty Bonds.” According to Woodrow Wilson’s postmaster general, Albert Burleson, anyone who dared to allege that “the Government is controlled by Wall Street or munitions manufacturers” could be arrested and prosecuted under the federal Sedition Act of 1918, enacted to curb wartime dissent.30
Calls for reform and regulation would be muffled in the postwar era. Following the 1917 Bolshevik Revolution in Russia, wartime campaigns against domestic radicals helped feed a “Red Scare” in 1919-20 targeting communists, anarchists, and labor unions, making any criticism of American business—or banking—potentially dangerous. True, some voices continued to assail Wall Street, including Senator Robert La Follette of Wisconsin, who ran unsuccessfully as the Progressive Party candidate for the presidency in 1924. His ally in the House of Representatives, a young resident of working-class Italian East Harlem named Fiorello La Guardia, nominated La Follette by declaring, “I speak for Avenue A and 116th Street, instead of Broad and Wall.”31
Paul Warburg, ca. 1915.
Library of Congress, Prints and Photograph Division
Paul Warburg was a founding visionary of the Federal Reserve System. Trained in his family’s century-old bank in Hamburg, Germany, he immigrated to New York in 1902 to join the Wall Street investment bank Kuhn, Loeb. Of his work in helping to create the Fed, a journalist remarked that Warburg was “the mildest-mannered man that ever personally conducted a revolution.”
Wall Street also suffered a violent attack on September 16, 1920 when an explosion ripped through the intersection of Wall, Broad, and Nassau Streets, killing 38 people and wounding 143 others. The bomb had been planted at the symbolic crossroads of American capitalism, between J.P. Morgan & Company at 23 Wall Street, the New York Stock Exchange across Broad Street, and 26 Wall Street, recently vacated by the U.S. Subtreasury. Although nobody ever claimed responsibility for the bombing and authorities failed to identify the culprit, the perpetrator was probably Mario Buda, an Italian-born anarchist who left the country shortly after the explosion. Its lasting consequence was to further discredit the entire American left, already facing a backlash for its opposition to World War I, militant postwar strikes, other anarchist bombings in 1919, and enthusiasm for the new Soviet Union.
Indeed, political criticism of New York’s banks had become unfashionable as well as risky. After a postwar recession ended in 1922, a booming industrial economy brought prosperity to millions across the country. As never before, credit became central to the nation’s consumer economy. Banks and their affiliates, such as the National City Company organized by the National City Bank, advertised aggressively to sell securities to middle-class salaried men and wage earners who had purchased Liberty bonds, stamps, and certificates during the war. Consumers relied on loans from banks, finance companies, and retailers to purchase everything from refrigerators and automobiles to homes. By the late 1920s, credit provided by banks and their affiliated securities companies to investors and speculators (a category that now included millions of Americans, not just the shifty gamblers of popular lore) was driving a roaring “bull market” on the New York Stock Exchange. By 1929, some 8 to 10 million American households possessed stocks.
Significantly, none of the existing regulatory mechanisms, including the Federal Reserve System, turned out to be an effective safeguard against the economic dangers of the speculative stock market of 1928-29, dangers few investors, brokers, politicians, or bankers wanted to face as stock prices continued on a dizzying upward trajectory. Neither federal nor state laws prevented feverish stock and bond speculation, or the ability of purchasers and brokers to buy “on margin”—to purchase easily and impulsively, because legally they had to pay only a fraction of the stock or bond price up front (usually only 10 to 20 percent). Brokers extended credit to buyers for the balance of the purchase price, provided by commercial banks and their securities affiliates in New York and across the nation eager to encourage investors’ optimism that securities prices (and hence profits) would continue to escalate. Nor did either the Federal Reserve Board in Washington or the Federal Reserve Bank of New York enforce more prudent policies as stock prices climbed higher and higher. In fact, Benjamin Strong, Jr., the domineering governor of the New York Fed, likely accelerated the bull market by keeping the Fed’s interest rates low and thus encouraging borrowing for speculation. (Strong did so because he wanted to help Britain return to and stay on the gold standard; low interest rates in the United States discouraged the flow of British gold to America.) Thus, before his death in late 1928, Strong inadvertently played a role in undermining one of the key purposes of the Federal Reserve System he had helped to create: to prevent speculative “booms” and “busts” by prudently raising interest rates and using open market operations to restrain reckless lending by other banks and creditors. Historians and pundits continue to argue over the role of the Fed in failing to prevent, and then exacerbating, the coming of the Great Depression in 1929, but most agree that the unwillingness of the Federal Reserve’s controlling officers to rein in an overheated securities market on Wall Street was a major contributing factor.

Brown Brothers, Wall Street bomb explosion, September 16, 1920.
Museum of the City of New York, X2010.11.3556
Bankers and Reformers
Between the end of the Civil War and the Jazz Age of the 1920s, numerous Americans challenged what they saw as the dangers posed to opportunity, equality, and democracy by New York’s banks. While “Wall Street” served as a symbol of disparate evils—capitalism, elitism, arrogance, secrecy, foreign influence, immigrants, Jews, urban life itself—beneath most of the complaints lay a deep discomfort with the sweeping economic changes that New York’s bankers symbolized and, indeed, played a major role in fostering. In this sense, Wall Street was an appropriate target for currency reformers, progressive investigators, and radicals. While insurgents succeeded in shaping laws (including the Armstrong laws, the Blue Sky laws, and the Clayton Antitrust Act) that regulated abuses and excesses, the process of banking and corporate consolidation that they most feared largely continued apace. New York bankers themselves entered the political arena in this era to beat back their critics. But they also played a role in re-envisioning the financial and monetary systems and eliminating some of their more flagrant shortcomings through the Federal Reserve System. The challenges posed by several generations of activists, critics, and voters largely waned in the “Roaring Twenties,” a prosperous and more conservative era. It would take another economic crisis—the worst in the nation’s history—to revive criticism of New York’s banks and to furnish reformers and radicals with new arguments and new tools.

Bains News Service, Liberty Loan parade, ca. 1918.
Library of Congress Prints and Photographs Division
Wall Street bankers submerged mutual resentments to join in backing the U.S. entry into World War I in 1917. Here, befitting his prestige, Jack Morgan (J. P. Morgan, Jr.) takes center stage, while Jacob Schiff of Kuhn, Loeb stands at the right as bankers prepare to march from Washington Square in a Liberty Loan parade.
1 “producing population,” “a vicious,” “Its headquarters”: Irwin Unger, The Greenback Era: A Social and Political History of American Finance, 1865–1879 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1964), 210.
2 “lead the people,” “money-power”: J. C. Zachos, ed., The Political and Financial Opinions of Peter Cooper. With an Autobiography of his Early Life (New York: Trow’s Printing and Bookbinding Company, 1877), 42–43; “NO MONEY MONOPOLY”: Edwin G. Burrows and Mike Wallace, Gotham: A History of New York City to 1898 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), 1091.
3 “the toiling masses”: Zachos, ed., Peter Cooper, 43.
4 “a good-looking, civil man” quoted in George P. Burnham, Memoirs of the United States Secret Service (Boston: Lee & Shepard, 1872), 422.
5 David R. Johnson, Illegal Tender: Counterfeiting and the Secret Service in Nineteenth-Century America (Washington: Smithsonian Institution Press, 1995), 76–77.
6 “as a class” quoted in Burnham, Memoirs of the United States Secret Service, 434; “Career of Joshua D. Miner; How a Notorious Counterfeiter was made to Change his Ways,” The New York Times, March 13, 1886.
7 “not only counterfeiting” quoted in Johnson, Illegal Tender, 82-83; “terra incognita”: Louis Bagger, “The Secret Service of the United States,” Appleton’s Journal, September 20, 1873, 360–365.
8 “cremation theory”: Unger, Greenback Era, 130.
9 “The Government itself”: Steve Fraser, Every Man a Speculator: A History of Wall Street in American Life (New York: HarperCollins, 2005), 211; “the business men”: W. H. Harvey, Coin’s Financial School (Chicago: Coin Publishing Company, 1894), 140; “A few men”: Mary Elizabeth Lease, The Problem of Civilization Solved (Chicago: Laird & Lee, 1895), 279.
10 “Wall Street”, “Jewish bankers”: Richard Hofstadter, The Age of Reform: From Bryan to F.D.R. (New York: Vintage, 1955), 79; Sarah E. Van de Vort Emery, Seven Financial Conspiracies which have Enslaved the American People (Lansing, MI: Robert Smith & Co., 1894), 16.
11 “composed of white men”: Ron Chernow, The House of Morgan: An American Banking Dynasty and the Rise of Modern Finance (New York: Grove Press, 1990), 103–104.
12 “Populistic communism”: Gretchen Ritter, Goldbugs and Greenbacks: The Antimonopoly Tradition and the Politics of Finance in America, 1865–1896 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 170.
13 “We do not wish”: Alfred Henry Lewis, ed., A Compilation of the Messages and Speeches of Theodore Roosevelt, 1901–1905 (N.p.: Bureau of National Literature and Art, 1906), 153.
14 “‘Standard Oil’ bank,” David Mark Chalmers, The Muckrake Years (New York: D. Van Nostrand, 1974), 95; “Every scoundrel”: Thomas W. Lawson, “Lawson and his Critics,” Everybody’s Magazine XI, no. 7 (July 1904): 70.
15 “elimination of”: Vincent P. Carosso, Investment Banking in America: A History (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970), 114–115.
16 “Mr. Chairman”: Ibid., 115.
17 “the powerful grip”: Ibid., 141.
18 “resulted in great”: Ibid., 151.
19 “Publicity is”: Louis D. Brandeis, Other People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It, ed. with an introduction by Melvin I. Urofsky (Boston: Bedford Books of St. Martin’s Press, 1995), 89; “The time is coming”: Ibid., 155; “public feeling”: Susie J. Pak, Gentlemen Bankers: The World of J. P. Morgan (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2013), 35.
20 “was a raging”: Brandeis, Other People’s Money, 31.
21 “curse of bigness”: Ibid., 120; “the old idea,” Morgan-Untermyer dialogue: Carosso, Investment Banking in America, 138, 149.
22 “The robbers”: George W. Walling, Recollections of a New York Chief of Police (New York: Caxton Book Concern, Limited, 1887), 249.
23 “the ‘cleanest job’”: “A Great Bank Robbery. The Manhattan Savings Institution Robbed,” The New York Times, Oct. 28, 1878 (ProQuest Historical Newspapers).
24 “monopolies are,” “the sense,” Schiff-Untermyer dialogue: Money Trust Investigation of Financial and Monetary Conditions in the United States under House Resolutions Nos. 429 and 504 Before a Subcommittee of the Committee on Banking and Currency, Part 23 (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1913), 1691, 1671, 1684.
25 “economic laws”: Carosso, Investment Banking in America, 151.
26 “there is little ground”: Ibid., 181.
27 “There is a”: Ibid., 139.
28 “Picture a party”: “Persons in the Foreground: How the Federal Reserve Bank was Evolved by Five Men on Jekyl Island,” Current Opinion LXI, no. 6 (December 1916: 382.
29 “free the political”: Jaffe, New York at War, 319.
30 “if there is”: Ibid., 318.
31 “I did not think,” “a Jew”: Ron Chernow, The Warburgs: The Twentieth-Century Odyssey of a Remarkable Jewish Family (New York: Random House, 1993), 137, 138.
32 “a cold-blooded”; “half-baked,” “the Government”: Steven H. Jaffe, New York at War: Four Centuries of Combat, Fear, and Intrigue in Gotham (New York: Basic Books, 2012), 203, 204.
33 “I speak for”: Arthur Mann, La Guardia: A Fighter Against His Times: 1882–1933 (Philadelphia: J. B. Lippincott, 1959), 171.