CHAPTER 4

Do Americans Care about Inequality?

THE ANALYSIS PRESENTED in chapter 3 suggests that much of the Republican Party's electoral success in the postwar era—and thus, much of the escalation in economic inequality associated with Republican administrations and policies—is a by-product of partisan biases in economic accountability. From the standpoint of democratic theory, that is a peculiarly unsatisfying conclusion. Good democrats like to think that government policy stems, directly or indirectly, from the will of the people. If it stems instead from such irrelevant quirks of voter psychology as myopia, misperceptions, and responsiveness to campaign spending, the warm glow seems distinctly diminished.

Democratic optimists, however, will note that elections are by no means the only possible avenue by which the will of the people may shape public policy. Political science provides many examples of analyses suggesting that public opinion may have significant direct effects on public policy regardless of whether Republicans or Democrats happen to be in charge.1 Thus, my accounts of policy-making in chapters 5 through 9 will involve careful weighing of the apparent influence of public sentiment, on one hand, and partisan elite ideology, on the other.

Assessing and interpreting the role of public opinion in the policy-making process requires, first, some clear understanding of what that public opinion is. Citizens may have crystallized views regarding specific matters of public policy, or they may not.2 Insofar as citizens do have meaningful policy preferences, those preferences may be internally consistent and sensibly related to their broader political values, or they may not.3 Public opinion touching on issues related to inequality is likely to be especially complex given the deep and multifaceted resonance of the value of equality in American political culture.

Much popular commentary suggests that ordinary Americans find inequality both natural and unobjectionable—that the ideal of equality, despite its prominence in our official ideology, has little real resonance in American political culture. According to sociologist Nathan Glazer, for example, “Americans, unlike the citizens of other prosperous democracies, not to mention those of poor countries, do not seem to care much about inequality. … [E]ven after the Enron and other scandals, most Americans remain apathetic about inequality: What we have today is outrage against those who do not play fair—not outrage over inequality as such.” In a similar vein, business writer Robert Samuelson argued that, “on the whole, Americans care less about inequality—the precise gap between the rich and the poor—than about opportunity and achievement: are people getting ahead?”4

Analysts of American ideology have often emphasized the potential for conflict and contradiction between the core values of economic opportunity and political equality. For example, Jennifer Hochschild found that people have quite distinct normative intuitions about economic, social, and political inequality. In the economic domain, her rich and poor respondents tended to “agree on a principle of differentiation, not of equality. … They define political freedom as strict equality, but economic freedom as an equal chance to become unequal.” Similarly, Herbert McClosky and John Zaller wrote that vast differences in wealth and life chances result “partly from the play of economic interests and the desire of those who have prospered to retain their advantages, and partly from the widespread acceptance of a powerful set of values associated with the private enterprise system that conflicts with egalitarianism.” Stanley Feldman provided evidence that people use distinct, often conflicting principles to assess “micro-justice” (individual rewards) and “macro-justice” (the social distribution of rewards).5

In light of these conflicts and complexities, it should not be surprising that analysts have also noted important exceptions to the general pattern of acceptance of economic inequality. For example, Hochschild found that “almost everyone, rich and poor, is incensed that the very wealthy do not pay their fair share of taxes. They argue that loopholes are too large and that the tax structure itself is insufficiently progressive.” McClosky and Zaller noted “signs of resentment toward the advantages enjoyed by corporations and the wealthy. A sizable majority of the mass public believes that corporations and the rich ‘really run the country,’ that they do not pay their fair shares of taxes, and that they receive better treatment in the courts than poor people do. A fair number of respondents (though not a majority) also believe that the laws mostly favor the rich.”6

In this chapter I explore three important facets of Americans' views about equality. First, I examine public support for broad egalitarian values and the political consequences of that support. Second, I examine public attitudes toward salient economic groups, including rich people, poor people, big business, and labor unions, among others. Third, I examine public perceptions of inequality and opportunity, including perceptions of growing economic inequality, normative assessments of that trend, and explanations for disparities in economic status—and how these views are shaped by the interaction of political information and political ideology.

The first half of the chapter provides strong evidence of the importance of egalitarian values in American political culture. The vast majority of Americans express support for equality in the abstract, and perhaps more surprisingly, those egalitarian values are translated into support for a variety of concrete social welfare policies, including government services, employment programs, health insurance, and aid to African-Americans. At a more visceral level, survey respondents say that they feel much warmer toward “working-class people” and “poor people” than toward “business people” and “rich people”—and those class feelings, too, bolster support for egalitarian policies. Most people also believe that the rich pay less than they should in taxes.

All of this sounds like fertile ground for a populist backlash against the escalating inequality of the New Gilded Age. Perhaps it is. However, the second half of this chapter provides some significant grounds for doubt. Three-fourths of Americans said that “the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people in the United States today” was larger than it was 20 years ago, but those responses appear to reflect cynical folk wisdom more than close attention to actual economic trends. The proportion of the public agreeing with the sardonic adage that “the rich get richer and the poor get poorer” increased markedly in the 1960s and early 1970s—a period in which the poor became rather less poor, though poverty became more salient. However, the substantial increase in economic inequality over the following three decades had virtually no effect on perceptions of inequality. Meanwhile, among people who did recognize that income differences had increased, more than one-third said that they had not thought about whether that was a good thing or a bad thing.

Public ignorance and inattention have important implications for the politics of inequality—implications I shall explore in more detail in chapters 5 and 6. However, my consideration of public opinion in the realm of inequality also highlights a very different limitation on the translation of egalitarian values into populist politics. Whereas uninformed people may often fail to grasp the political relevance of their beliefs and values, well-informed people may often deny or distort inconvenient facts, preserving a false consistency between their beliefs about the causes, extent, and meaning of inequality in contemporary American society, on one hand, and their ideological or partisan predilections, on the other. In this way, too, genuine allegiance to the ideal of equality may comfortably coexist with fervent support for policies that exacerbate inequality.

EGALITARIAN VALUES

Sure, we hold this truth to be self-evident, that all men are created equal. But it is far from self-evident what that means. Is it inconsistent with American ideals for corporate CEOs to earn 300 times as much as their workers? Are ordinary Americans offended by the fact that the top 1% of income-earners have hauled in more than half of the nation's total gains in real income over the past two decades? Is it wrong for millions of children to grow up without access to decent schools and routine health care? If not, then escalating economic inequality may, after all, be a perfectly understandable and unobjectionable outcome of (small “d”) democratic politics.

One useful starting point in examining public thinking about economic inequality in the New Gilded Age is to assess people's allegiance to equality as a general value, sidestepping for the moment the complexities that may arise in applying that value to specific cases. While it would be foolhardy to confuse pronouncements of support for equality in the abstract with support for specific policies promoting specific kinds of equality in specific circumstances, it would be equally foolhardy to deny that people's allegiance to abstract values may have important practical political consequences.

As it happens, American National Election Studies surveys over the past three decades have regularly asked random samples of Americans a detailed battery of questions about egalitarian values, as well as questions about a wide variety of concrete political issues in which equality might figure as an important consideration. Responses to these questions make it possible to gauge the extent and bases of public support for equality in the abstract—and to assess the impact of egalitarian values on specific policy preferences. Table 4.1 provides a summary of the responses.7

TABLE 4.1

Public Support for Egalitarian Values

 

Agree strongly

Agree somewhat

Neither; DK

Disagree somewhat

Disagree strongly

Our society should do whatever is necessary to make sure that everyone has an equal opportunity to succeed

60.9%

26.8%

5.4%

4.8%

2.0%

If people were treated more equally in this country, we would have many fewer problems

32.4%

33.7%

14.2%

14.2%

5.4%

One of the big problems in this country is that we don't give everyone an equal chance

22.6%

29.9%

13.6%

23.0%

10.8%

It is not really that big a problem if some people have more of a chance in life than others

7.7%

23.9%

19.2%

28.2%

20.9%

We have gone too far in pushing equal rights in this country

15.9%

28.1%

16.0%

20.6%

19.3%

The country would be better off if we worried less about how equal people are

18.6%

28.8%

16.0%

20.7%

15.9%

Source: 1984–2012 ANES surveys. N = 19,357–20,652.

The first question in table 4.1 has consistently elicited the most enthusiastically egalitarian opinion. In periodic surveys going back to the early 1980s, more than 85% of Americans have agreed that “our society should do whatever is necessary to make sure that everyone has an equal opportunity to succeed,” and more than 60% have agreed strongly with that statement. Interpreted literally, these responses imply an astounding level of public support for what would have to be a very radical program of social transformation. Inherited wealth would have to be outlawed; local funding of public schools would have to cease; every child would have to be assigned competent and loving parents; and prejudices based on race, ethnicity, religion, and sex would have to be eradicated, along with social and economic advantages derived from intelligence, physical attractiveness, and freakish athletic skills. Of course, this is not really what people mean when they agree that we “should do whatever is necessary to make sure that everyone has an equal opportunity to succeed.” Nevertheless, their willingness to endorse such a statement, even as a matter of verbal ritual, provides a striking testament to the force of “equal opportunity” in American culture.

More generally, the questions in table 4.1 referring to “an equal chance” or equal treatment generated favorable responses from half to two-thirds of the respondents, while those referring to “how equal people are” and “pushing equal rights” were rather less popular.8 These differences suggest a consequential distinction in public thinking between equality of opportunity and equality of results. Nevertheless, more detailed analysis of individual response patterns suggests that there is a fair degree of consistency in people's responses to all six questions, regardless of their precise wording. Thus, it is convenient to combine responses to all six questions in a summary scale measuring general support for egalitarian values.9 The summary scale values range from −1 to +1, with an average value of +.21. Twenty percent of the ANES respondents had very egalitarian scale scores (in excess of +.5), while fewer than 3% had very inegalitarian scores (below −.5).

Of course, given the high level of generality of the survey items comprising the egalitarian values scale, it is possible that the responses to these items represent little more than lip service to the ideal of equality. Do they have any real, concrete political impact? The analyses presented in table 4.2 suggest that they do. These analyses show that people who were more egalitarian took much more liberal positions on each of the major social welfare policy issues that have appeared consistently in ANES surveys over the past three decades—support for government jobs and income maintenance,10 for government spending and services,11 for government aid to blacks,12 and for government health insurance.13

TABLE 4.2:

Egalitarian Values and Policy Preferences

Ordinary least squares regression parameter estimates (with standard errors in parentheses). Policy preferences range from 1 (for the most conservative position) to 7 (for the most liberal position). Observations clustered by year; year-specific intercepts not shown.

 

Government jobs

Government services

Aid to blacks

Health insurance

Egalitarian values only

Egalitarian values (−1 to +1)

1.69
(.10)

1.40
(.06)

1.68
(.03)

1.39
(.12)

Standard error of regression

1.69

1.49

1.60

1.86

Adjusted R2

.14

.14

.16

.09

N

14,625

14,883

16,456

11,674

Egalitarian values, ideology, and party identification

Egalitarian values (−1 to +1)

1.23
(.10)

.89
(.06)

1.35
(.05)

.72
(.08)

Liberal ideology (−1 to +1)

.49
(.05)

.53
(.06)

.41
(.02)

.75
(.08)

Democratic party identification (−1 to +1)

.49
(0.3)

.50
(.04)

.31
(.05)

.61
(.05)

Standard error of regression

1.63

1.42

1.57

1.77

Adjusted R2

.20

.22

.19

.18

N

14,183

14,472

16,009

11,220

Source: 1984–2012 ANES surveys.

The analyses reported in the top panel of the table show how positions on each of these issues varied with attachment to egalitarian values. For government jobs and aid to blacks, the most egalitarian people were, on average, more than three points to the left of the most inegalitarian people on the seven-point policy scale—a difference between moderately liberal positions, on one hand, and solidly conservative positions, on the other. For views about government spending and services and health insurance, the average differences were almost as large, about 2.8 points.

Of course, people's views about equality are strongly correlated with their broader political ideology and partisanship. Thus, one may wonder whether the strong relationships documented in the top panel of table 4.2 are simply reflections of these more concrete political allegiances. However, that does not turn out to be the case. Not surprisingly, liberals and Democrats were significantly more supportive of government action in each of these issue areas than conservatives and Republicans were.14 Nevertheless, even after taking account of differences in policy preferences attributable to ideology and partisanship, the analyses presented in the bottom panel of table 4.2 suggest that egalitarian values had a substantial independent impact. For two of the four issues (government jobs and aid to blacks), the estimated effects of egalitarian values on policy preferences exceeded the combined effects of ideology and partisanship.

The fact that social welfare policy preferences seem to be strongly shaped by broader views about equality is especially important in light of the overall level of support for egalitarian values in the American public. If opponents of equality were just as numerous as proponents of equality, even the strong effects of egalitarian values on policy preferences reported in table 4.2 would not alter the average levels of public support for government action in these policy areas. However, the combination of net support for egalitarian values in table 4.1 and strong effects of egalitarian values on policy preferences in table 4.2 translates into significant additional net public support for liberal policies. For the issues of government jobs and aid to blacks, the overall distributions of public opinion are a good deal less conservative than they would otherwise be; for the issues of government services and health insurance, distributions of opinion that would otherwise be precisely balanced between liberal and conservative extremes instead lean in a liberal direction.15 In this respect, at least, Americans' support for egalitarian values is much more than just lip service—it has significant political consequences. As Sidney Verba and Gary Orren put it, “values are instrumental in shaping the public policies that give practical effect to political belief.”16

RICH AND POOR

Ordinary people's responses to such abstract questions as whether we should “make sure that everyone has an equal opportunity to succeed” or whether we have “gone too far in pushing equal rights in this country” turn out to be strongly related to their views about important issues of public policy. However, it seems unlikely that most public thinking about inequality occurs at such a high level of abstraction. Indeed, political scientists have amassed a good deal of evidence suggesting that ordinary citizens engage in rather little abstract reasoning in most realms of politics, relying instead on positive or negative attitudes toward salient social groups to shape their reactions to specific public policies, political candidates, and social conditions.17

In the realm of economic inequality, such salient groups might include rich people, poor people, big business, and the working class, among others. ANES surveys over the years have measured public attitudes toward these and a variety of other social groups using a “feeling thermometer.” Survey respondents are invited to rate each group on a scale ranging from 0 to 100, with 50 meaning “you don't feel particularly warm or cold” toward the group, ratings above 50 representing “favorable and warm” feelings, and ratings below 50 representing “unfavorable and cool” feelings. Table 4.3 reports the average thermometer ratings for various groups in the 2004–2012 ANES surveys. The groups are listed in order of popularity: at one extreme, “working-class people” received an average rating of 83 out of 100; at the other extreme, the Republican Party received an average rating of 50—just below Muslims and gay men and lesbians.

TABLE 4.3

Average “Feeling Thermometer” Ratings for Social Groups

Ratings range from zero (least favorable) to 100 (most favorable).

 

2004

2008

2012

Average

Working-class people

82.6

82.7

83.9

83.1

The military

79.8

79.6

83.2

80.9

Middle-class people

76.8

76.4

77.3

76.8

Poor people

73.4

72.0

71.0

72.1

Business people

69.3

NA

NA

69.3

Catholics

69.0

67.3

66.3

67.5

Conservatives

60.9

60.3

57.6

59.6

The Democratic Party

58.7

57.2

55.3

57.1

Rich people

59.5

57.3

54.2

57.0

Christian fundamentalists

58.8

56.3

53.4

56.2

Feminists

56.2

56.6

54.2

55.7

Labor unions

58.2

55.6

52.5

55.4

Big business

56.1

53.2

53.4

54.2

People on welfare

55.9

54.4

52.3

54.2

Liberals

54.9

54.7

52.1

53.9

Muslims

53.6

50.3

47.9

50.6

Gay men and lesbians

47.5

49.4

53.7

50.2

The Republican Party

53.9

47.7

47.2

49.6

N

1,003–1,178

1,886–2,259

1,777–2,012

Source: 2004–2012 ANES surveys.

What, if anything, do these feeling thermometer ratings suggest about the politics of inequality? To the extent that people's political views are colored by their sympathy for economic classes, they are, perhaps surprisingly, quite likely to side with poor people (with an average rating of 72) over rich people (with an average rating of 57). If anything, that gap has increased in recent years, from 14 points in 2004 to 15 points in 2008 and 17 points in 2012. While ordinary Americans may hope, and perhaps even expect, to become rich someday, in the meantime they express rather little warmth for those who have already made it. Big business fared even worse than rich people, with an average rating of 54—the same average rating as for people on welfare. The less pejorative phrase “business people” elicited much warmer feelings (with an average rating of 69); however, even business people were rated less favorably than poor people.

Labor unions (with an average rating of 55) fared slightly better than big business, but much worse than (presumably unorganized) working-class people. Indeed, working-class people (with an average rating of 83) were held in even higher esteem than middle-class people (with an average rating of 77). Given the frequent characterization of America as a society that exalts the middle class, it seems remarkable that most Americans express even more positive feelings about working-class people than about middle-class people.

If people understand and assess public policies, in part, on the basis of their implications for salient social groups, we might expect that the feelings toward the working class, the rich, and other economic groups summarized in table 4.3 would color views about issues like government spending and services and health insurance. The analyses in table 4.4 test this expectation by adding a summary measure of class sympathies to the analyses of policy preferences in table 4.2. The summary measure of class sympathies compares the warmth of people's feelings toward the poor, the working class, and labor unions, on one hand, and the rich, the middle class, and big business, on the other hand.

The results presented in table 4.4 suggest that class sympathies do have significant effects on policy preferences, over and above the effects of egalitarian values, political ideology, and party identification. Most people's class sympathies did not push them strongly in either direction (because they reported fairly warm feelings about all of the groups included in the summary measure). Nonetheless, those with moderately egalitarian class sympathies (one standard deviation above the mean) took positions that were about half a point more liberal than those with moderately inegalitarian class sympathies (one standard deviation below the mean) on three of the four seven-point scales. For these three policies—government jobs, government services, and health insurance—the estimated effects of class sympathies rival in importance the estimated effects of egalitarian values and ideology. (For aid to blacks, a policy domain in which class sympathies are presumably less relevant, the estimated effect was much smaller, about one-fifth of a point.)

TABLE 4.4

Class Sympathies and Policy Preferences

Ordinary least squares regression parameter estimates (with standard errors in parentheses). Policy preferences range from 1 (for the most conservative position) to 7 (for the most liberal position). Observations clustered by year; year-specific intercepts not shown.

 

Government jobs

Government services

Aid to blacks

Health insurance

Class sympathies (−1 to +1)

1.69
(.14)

1.39
(.34)

.56
(.26)

1.51
(.19)

Egalitarian values (−1 to +1)

.92
(.04)

.66
(.10)

1.07
(.05)

.56
(.04)

Liberal ideology (−1 to +1)

.56
(.05)

.56
(.07)

.34
(.03)

.93
(.06)

Democratic Party identification (−1 to +1)

.55
(.04)

.59
(.10)

.54
(.03)

.57
(.17)

Standard error of regression

1.55

1.35

1.57

1.67

Adjusted R2

.28

.32

.22

.26

N

3,426

3,241

4,076

3,487

Source: 2004–2012 ANES surveys.

The 2002 and 2004 ANES surveys included another set of questions tapping attitudes toward rich people and poor people in the specific context of a policy issue where class sympathies are presumably even more relevant. These questions asked whether rich people, poor people, and the respondents themselves are asked to pay too much, too little, or about the right amount in federal income taxes. The distributions of responses to these questions are presented in table 4.5.18

As with the feeling thermometer ratings of rich people and poor people, these responses demonstrate a rather striking skew in favor of the poor over the rich. For example, 45% of the ANES respondents said that poor people are asked to pay more than they should in federal income taxes, while only 13% said that rich people are asked to pay more than they should. More than half the respondents said that rich people are asked to pay less than they should, while only 8% said that poor people are asked to pay less than they should. Of course, these responses may be based on very inaccurate perceptions of how much rich people and poor people actually pay in federal income taxes. Still, if taken at face value, they seem to demonstrate substantial public support for increasing, rather than decreasing, the progressivity of the tax system.

TABLE 4.5

Perceived Tax Burdens

“Do you feel you are asked to pay more than you should in federal income taxes, about the right amount, or less than you should? What about rich people? What about poor people?”

 

2002

2004

Average

Own tax burden

Pay more than I should

48.3%

39.6%

44.0%

Pay about the right amount

46.2%

51.2%

48.7%

Pay less than I should

3.8%

4.8%

4.3%

Rich people

Pay more than they should

15.3%

10.3%

12.8%

Pay about the right amount

29.9%

24.9%

27.4%

Pay less than they should

53.2%

60.4%

56.8%

Poor people

Pay more than they should

45.8%

46.3%

46.1%

Pay about the right amount

43.7%

42.1%

42.9%

Pay less than they should

8.7%

7.0%

7.8%

N

1,495–1,504

1,210–1,211

Source: 2002 and 2004 ANES surveys.

Respondents' perceptions regarding their own tax burdens were not too different from their perceptions regarding the tax burdens borne by poor people. Fewer than 5% said that they are asked to pay less than they should, but almost half said that they are asked to pay “about the right amount.” The proportion who said that they are asked to pay too much was almost identical to the proportion who said that poor people are asked to pay too much (43% versus 45%). Insofar as these results imply any sort of class solidarity on the part of ordinary Americans, it is class solidarity with the poor rather than with the rich.

People's attitudes about the tax burdens of the rich and the poor—like their attitudes about these groups more generally—reveal a good deal less sympathy for the rich, and a good deal more sympathy for the poor, than one might expect. While it may be true that “Americans do not go in for envy,” as a report in The Economist put it, neither do they seem especially solicitous of rich people or their problems.19 Nor do they seem to be punitive in their attitudes toward poor people, except when the focus is shifted to “people on welfare,” and even they are viewed about as warmly as big business, and more warmly than the Republican Party. Insofar as the policy preferences of ordinary citizens are colored by their class sympathies, those sympathies are more likely to reinforce broadly egalitarian values than to negate them.

PERCEPTIONS OF INEQUALITY

Ordinary citizens' values and sympathies are likely to be politically significant only when they are connected to consequential political actors or issues. But the political activation of values and sympathies is far from automatic. For example, egalitarian impulses are likely to gain real political traction only when citizens perceive contradictions between egalitarian ideals and social realities.20 Given the enormous complexity of politics and public affairs, connections of that sort may require a good deal of political information and attention. As the acute political observer Walter Lippmann noted almost a century ago, the fact that much everyday political thinking occurs in a “pseudo-environment” only loosely connected to social reality often postpones or prevents “the murder of a Beautiful Theory by a Gang of Brutal Facts.”21

In the present context, it seems well worth exploring how much ordinary Americans know about the Brutal Facts of escalating inequality sketched in chapter 1. Recent ANES surveys have included a variety of questions probing respondents' perceptions of economic inequality, its causes, and its consequences. Table 4.6 presents the distribution of responses to a question in the 2002–2012 surveys assessing people's recognition of growing income inequality. The question asked whether “the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people in the United States today is larger, smaller, or about the same as it was 20 years ago.” Those who said “larger” or “smaller” were asked whether the difference was much larger or smaller or only somewhat larger or smaller.

The distribution of responses in table 4.6 seems to demonstrate widespread public recognition of the sheer fact of growing economic inequality in contemporary America. Overall, almost 80% of the ANES respondents said that the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people was larger than it was 20 years ago, and almost half said it was much larger. Only about 5% said it was smaller.

TABLE 4.6

Perceptions of Economic Inequality

“Do you think the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people in the United States today is larger, smaller, or about the same as it was 20 years ago?”

 

2002

2004

2008

2012

Average

Much larger

42.2%

47.9%

54.9%

52.5%

49.4%

Somewhat larger

32.3%

31.1%

23.7%

26.8%

28.5%

About the same

16.3%

15.9%

13.9%

10.4%

14.1%

Somewhat smaller

6.0%

2.5%

4.2%

3.6%

4.1%

Much smaller

1.8%

0.3%

1.3%

1.7%

1.3%

Don't know

1.5%

2.2%

2.0%

5.1%

2.7%

N

1,508

1,065

2,099

2,051

Source: 2002–2012 ANES surveys.

However, the reality of this apparent recognition is called into question by the stability of Americans' perceptions of inequality over the past half-century. As it turns out, survey respondents have consistently been quite likely to endorse the notion that inequality is increasing, regardless of actual economic trends. In a detailed survey of Americans' awareness of rising inequality, Leslie McCall presented a time series dating back to the mid-1970s of responses to a Harris poll question asking, “Do you tend to feel or not feel that … the rich get richer and the poor get poorer?” As McCall summarized her results, “this question does not appear to be tapping perceptions of high levels of inequality, or at least not perceptions that are accurate. Nor is it necessarily tapping a more general sense that inequality is rising in one period (the 1990s) as compared to an earlier period (the 1970s). Moreover, the vast majority of Americans agree throughout the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s, that American society is structured in a way that benefits the rich and penalizes the poor, or more loosely that rising inequality is a natural state of affairs.”22

Figure 4.1 presents an even longer tracking of responses to the Harris question, derived from 51 surveys conducted between April 1966 and May 2011. The responses to the Harris question over this longer period do show a significant increase in public perceptions of economic inequality. However, that increase was concentrated in the late 1960s and early 1970s—a period in which actual economic inequality was modest by today's standards and probably not yet increasing.

images

FIGURE 4.1 Americans' Perceptions That “the Rich Get Richer and the Poor Get Poorer,” 1966–2011

By 1973, about three-quarters of the Harris respondents agreed that “the rich get richer and the poor get poorer.” That percentage fluctuated in a fairly narrow band (from a low of 65% to a high of 83%) for the next four decades. There is some evidence of an increase in the late 1980s and early 1990s, with a corresponding decline in the mid to late 1990s, but these shifts were quite modest. The remarkable fact is that, by this measure, perceptions of economic inequality were less prevalent under George W. Bush and Barack Obama than they had been under Gerald Ford and Jimmy Carter.

The fact that public perceptions of economic inequality bear so little relationship to actual trends in inequality must temper any overly optimistic assessment of the extent to which ordinary people are aware of changes in the relative fortunes of the rich and the poor. However, it does not follow that perceptions of economic inequality are meaningless or politically inconsequential. Even a ritualistic endorsement of the folk wisdom that “the rich get richer and the poor get poorer” may signal unhappiness with this apparently self-reinforcing reality. But then again, it may not.

TABLE 4.7

Assessments of Economic Inequality

“Do you think the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people in the United States today is larger, smaller, or about the same as it was 20 years ago? [If larger or smaller,] do you think this is a good thing, a bad thing, or haven't you thought about it?”

 

A good thing

A bad thing

Haven't thought about it; DK

Total

Much larger

2.4%

31.6%

10.6%

44.6%

Somewhat larger

2.1%

12.4%

17.3%

31.9%

About the same

16.1%

Somewhat smaller

1.5%

0.5%

2.5%

4.6%

Much smaller

0.3%

0.6%

0.2%

1.1%

Don't know

1.7%

Total

6.3%

45.2%

30.6%

100%

Source: 2002 and 2004 ANES surveys. N = 2,573.

In the 2002 and 2004 ANES surveys, people who said that differences in income had gotten larger (or smaller) were also asked whether that change was “a good thing” or “a bad thing.” The distribution of responses to that question is shown in table 4.7. Among those who said that inequality had increased, most thought that was “a bad thing,” but a substantial minority said that they hadn't thought about whether it was a good thing or a bad thing. (Fewer than 6% said that increasing inequality was a good thing.)

If we ask where there is potential political support for egalitarian redistribution in these responses, the obvious place to begin is with the 32% of the public who said that the difference in incomes between rich and poor was much larger than it had been and that that was a bad thing. Those people were at the core of a somewhat larger group—44% of the public—who both recognized and regretted the fact that economic inequality had increased. In contrast, outright supporters of economic inequality—those who applauded the fact that inequality had increased or believed with regret that inequality had declined—constituted less than 6% of the public.

The remainder of the public was divided into two broad groups. The first of these, consisting of about 24% of the total population, did not recognize that economic inequality had increased. (Most of these people said that the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people was “about the same” as 20 years ago; the rest thought that it had decreased or said that they didn't know.) People in this group lacked, but could conceivably acquire, a factual basis for seeing growing economic inequality as a social problem. The second group, even more numerous (about 28% of the total population), recognized that inequality had increased, but had not thought about whether that was good or bad. What these people seem to have lacked was a moral basis for seeing growing economic inequality as a social problem.

Perhaps, like a few of the people in Jennifer Hochschild's much more detailed conversations about distributive justice, people in this second group “do not seek redistribution because they do not care one way or the other about it.” But if her respondents are indicative, it is more likely that they “are not forced to face the question of redistribution” in their day-to-day lives and thus “fail to support any system of distributive justice very fully. They sometimes seek equality; at other times, they seek differentiation; too often, they do not know what they want or even how to decide what the possibilities are.”23

In addition to asking respondents about their perceptions and evaluations of economic inequality, the 2002 ANES survey included a battery of questions inviting respondents to explain why, “in America today, some people have better jobs and higher incomes than others do.”24 The survey offered a variety of potential explanations ranging from “some people just don't work as hard” to “discrimination holds some people back” to “God made people different from one another.” Respondents were asked to indicate whether each potential explanation was “very important,” “somewhat important,” or “not important.” Their answers are summarized in table 4.8, which lists the seven potential explanations in order of popularity.

The quintessential American belief that economic success is a matter of hard work fares well in table 4.8, with 45% of the public saying that unequal effort is a “very important” cause of economic inequality. However, there is even more support (about 55%) for the notion that unequal access to a good education is very important. Two other social factors, discrimination and government policies, also loom fairly large as explanations for economic inequality. And while one-third of the respondents said that differences in “inborn ability to learn” are very important, almost half rejected the idea that income differences exist because “God made people different from one another.” These responses certainly do not suggest that most Americans view economic inequality as a merely natural phenomenon, even if they do think it is attributable in part to differences in character and ability.

TABLE 4.8

Explanations for Economic Inequality

“Next, we'd like to know why you think it is, that in America today, some people have better [worse] jobs and higher [lower] incomes than others do. I'm going to read you some possible explanations, and I want you to tell me how important you think each is—very important, somewhat important, or not important at all.”

 

Very important

Somewhat important

Not important

Some people don't get a chance to get a good education

54.5%

35.1%

9.1%

Some people just don't work as hard

44.7%

41.4%

12.9%

Some people have more inborn ability to learn

33.8%

42.1%

23.4%

Discrimination holds some people back

26.4%

50.2%

22.5%

Government policies have helped high-income workers more

26.0%

38.2%

33.6%

Some people just choose low-paying jobs

19.4%

38.8%

39.6%

God made people different from one another

22.2%

26.5%

48.5%

Source: 2002 ANES survey. N = 1,427.

Some evidence also suggests that Americans’ attitudes about economic inequality may have shifted in recent years. In a 1987 survey conducted as part of the International Social Survey Programme, Americans were evenly split on the question of whether “large income differences are necessary for a country's prosperity.” But support for that proposition had declined noticeably in a follow-up survey conducted in 1992 and declined still further by 1999, to a level almost identical to those prevailing in the United Kingdom, Germany, Spain, Sweden, and Norway. Over the same 12-year period, the differences in salaries that respondents considered appropriate for people in a variety of specific jobs declined by almost 25%. These results suggest that Americans probably have less tolerance for economic inequality than they used to, and even that their views about its necessity are not much different from those prevailing in other, more egalitarian democracies.25

FACTS AND VALUES IN THE REALM OF INEQUALITY

So, do Americans care about inequality? Here, as so often, it is easy to disagree about whether the glass is half full or half empty. Almost 45% of Americans say that the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people has increased over the past 20 years and that that is a bad thing—but an even larger proportion either do not acknowledge the fact or have not thought about whether it is good or bad. More than 60% agree that government policies have exacerbated economic inequality by helping high-income workers more, but more than one-third disagree, and more than 85% say that “some people just don't work as hard.” Half the public thinks that rich people are asked to pay less than they should in federal income taxes—but almost half does not think so.

What accounts for these differences in perceptions of inequality and its causes and implications? In particular, why is there so much apparent resistance to acknowledging the extent of inequality in a society where more than 85% of the public agrees that we “should do whatever is necessary to make sure that everyone has an equal opportunity to succeed”?

Psychologists have spent considerable scholarly energy elaborating “just world” or “system justification” theories. Their basic idea is that “living in an unpredictable, uncontrollable, and capriciously unjust world would be unbearably threatening, and so we cling defensively to the illusion that the world is a just place.” In the economic realm, one result is a widespread belief in the basic fairness of capitalism, even among people who seem to be on the losing end of the free-market system. At the individual level, similar psychological pressures produce unrealistic optimism about one's own economic prospects and an illusion of control over uncontrollable events, both “adaptive forms of self-deception that facilitate coping with environmental stress and uncertainty.”26

Although the psychological urge to deny injustice and economic vulnerability is presumably universal, some scholars have maintained that political conservatives are, as a matter of personality, especially sensitive to the stresses of an unpredictable, uncontrollable environment—and thus especially strongly motivated to deny its threatening features. On the other hand, conservatives may be especially likely to downplay the potentially troubling features of the prevailing economic system, not because they have fundamentally different personalities but simply because they are psychologically committed to a belief in the justice and efficiency of that system. As one study put it, “conservatism is a prototypical system-justifying ideology, in that it preserves the status quo and provides intellectual and moral justification for maintaining inequality in society.” Either way, we might expect ideological rationalization to produce considerable consistency between perceptions of fact and assessments of value in the realm of inequality.27

TABLE 4.9

Political Ideology and Perceptions of Inequality

Ordered probit parameter estimates (with standard errors in parentheses). Additional response thresholds not shown.

 

The income gap has increased

The larger gap is a bad thinga

The poor don't get a fair trial

Hard work is very important

Conservative ideology (−1 to +1)

−.298
(.049)

−.560
(.062)

−.418
(.077)

.408
(.066)

Family income (0 to 1)

.091
(.081)

.509
(.101)

.240
(.128)

−.201
(.110)

2004 survey

.229
(.044)

.121
(.054)

Intercept

.639
(.053)

−.066
(.063)

.670
(.072)

−.058
(.064)

Log likelihood

−3,040.4

−1,644.5

−1,010.6

−1,378.8

Pseudo-R2

.01

.03

.02

.01

N

2,525

1,976

1,499

1,414

Source: 2002 and 2004 ANES surveys.

a Includes only those respondents who said that the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people has increased.

The statistical analyses reported in table 4.9 shed further light on the ideological bases of differences in perceptions of the extent and implications of economic inequality in American society. The questions on which these analyses are based range from purely factual—whether “the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people in the United States today is larger, smaller, or about the same as it was 20 years ago”—to purely normative—whether increasing income differences are “a good thing” or “a bad thing.” The analyses also include two questions from the 2002 ANES survey that are factual in nature but less straightforward than the question about the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people. One of these questions asked whether “a poor person has the same chance of getting a fair trial as a wealthy person does”; the other asked whether the fact that “some people just don't work as hard” is a “very important” explanation for economic inequality. For each of these questions, the table shows how responses varied with political ideology. (The analyses also allow for differences due to family income levels, as well as for differences in responses between 2002 and 2004 for questions asked in both years.)

Perhaps unsurprisingly, the largest effect of political ideology was on responses to the purely normative question—whether the increasing difference in incomes between rich people and poor people is a good thing or a bad thing. (People who said that the difference in incomes had not increased or that they did not know—about 24% of the ANES respondents—are excluded from this analysis.) Extreme conservatives were only half as likely as extreme liberals to say that growing inequality is a bad thing (38% versus 79%) and almost three times as likely to say that it is a good thing or (more commonly) that they had not thought about whether it was good or bad (62% versus 21%).28 This difference underlines the extent to which “conservatism … provides intellectual and moral justification for maintaining inequality in society.”29

It should not be surprising that conservatism provides moral justification for inequality. However, it should be surprising that ideological commitments also had substantial effects on responses to the factual questions included in the table. Extreme conservatives were twice as likely as extreme liberals to say that hard work is a very important explanation for income differences (60% versus 28%). They were also more than three times as likely as extreme liberals to insist that poor people have the same access to justice that rich people do (36% versus 11%), though even most extreme conservatives disagreed with this proposition. Given the complexity of these questions and the paucity of hard evidence available to adjudicate them, liberals and conservatives managed to construct very different, ideologically congenial pictures of the social reality of inequality.

Even in the case of the most straightforwardly factual question included in the table—whether the income gap between rich and poor had increased—the responses of conservatives and liberals were strongly colored by their ideological perspectives. Almost 90% of extreme liberals, but only 73% of extreme conservatives, thought that income differences had increased. Put the other way, conservatives were more than twice as likely as liberals to deny that the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people had grown larger. In light of the magnitude of the economic trends described in chapter 1, it is striking that more than one in four extreme conservatives persisted in believing that income differences between rich people and poor people have not, in fact, increased over the past two decades.

The statistical results presented in table 4.9 are derived from the responses of a representative national sample of the adult population. Such a sample includes many people who pay little attention to news and have only the vaguest grasp of public affairs. If these inattentive citizens relied on ideological surmise because they lacked solid information about actual trends in economic inequality, the ideological disparities in perceptions evident in the table might simply reflect the (potentially remediable) limits of civic education in this domain.

In order to address that possibility, the statistical analyses presented in table 4.9 must be elaborated to allow for the (potentially distinct) effects of political information within each ideological group. I do that using general measures of political information in the ANES surveys. The 2004 ANES survey included questions asking: (1) which party had more members in the House of Representatives prior to the election; (2) which party had more members in the Senate prior to the election; (3) which party was more conservative at the national level; (4) what job or political office Dennis Hastert held; (5) what job or office Dick Cheney held; (6) what job or office Tony Blair held; and (7) what job or office William Rehnquist held. I constructed a political information scale based on correct answers to these seven questions. (Two of the 1,066 respondents answered all seven questions correctly; 22% gave five or more correct answers, while 42% gave two or fewer correct answers.) The 2002 ANES survey did not include an analogous battery of factual questions about politics; instead, I employed a subjective rating of respondents’ “general level of information about politics and public affairs” (on a five-point scale ranging from “very low” to “very high”) provided by the interviewer at the end of each interview.30

When the ANES survey respondents are differentiated on the basis of political information, it appears that general political awareness makes people markedly more pessimistic on a variety of scores about the extent and implications of inequality in contemporary America. The statistical results presented in table 4.10 imply that people at the top of the information scale were more likely than those at the bottom to say that income differences had increased (84% versus 74%) and much more likely to see that as a bad thing (73% versus 46%). They were also more likely to deny that “a poor person has the same chance of getting a fair trial as a wealthy person does” (85% versus 71%).31 These differences and others suggest that better-informed people have distinctive views about the nature, sources, and consequences of economic inequality.32

Most of the differences between better-informed and less-informed people in table 4.10 parallel those between liberals and conservatives in table 4.9. Better-informed people were more likely to say that income inequality had increased and more likely to say that was a bad thing. They were also more likely to say that poor people were disadvantaged in the legal system and (slightly) less likely to say that differences in hard work were a very important cause of inequality. In each of these respects, political information shifted people's views in the same direction as liberal political ideology.

Although the primary effects of political information and liberal ideology were generally reinforcing, table 4.10 also presents strong evidence of interactions between information and ideology: increasing political awareness seems to have had very different effects on liberals and conservatives. Indeed, for each of the four questions included in the table, greater political awareness shifted the views of liberals and conservatives in opposite directions.

This pattern is evident even for the most straightforwardly objective question analyzed in the table—whether differences in income between rich people and poor people had increased or decreased. The solid and dotted lines in figure 4.2 reflect the response tendencies of extreme liberals and extreme conservatives, respectively, based on the statistical results presented in table 4.10. At low levels of political information, the figure shows that conservatives and liberals were about equally likely to recognize that income differences had increased over the past 20 years. However, the perceptions of better-informed conservatives and liberals diverged significantly. Among liberals, recognition of increasing income inequality rose markedly with general political awareness, to 86% for people of average political awareness (corresponding to the open circle halfway along the solid line) and a near-unanimous 96% at the highest information level.33 However, the proportion of extreme conservatives who were willing to admit that economic inequality had increased actually decreased with political information, from 80% among those who were generally least informed about politics to 70% for people of average political awareness to a little less than 60% among those at the top of the distribution of political information.34 Conservatives who were generally better informed about politics were less likely to get this salient fact straight.

TABLE 4.10

Political Information, Ideology, and Perceptions of Inequality

Ordered probit parameter estimates (with standard errors in parentheses). Additional response thresholds not shown.

 

The income gap has increased

The larger gap is a bad thinga

The poor don't get a fair trial

Hard work is very important

Political information (0 to 1)

.365
(.093)

.728
(.117)

.470
(.165)

−.150
(.138)

Conservative ideology (−1 to +1)

.210
(.113)

.094
(.141)

−.111
(.191)

−.037
(.170)

Political information × ideology

−.971
(.193)

−1.294
(.251)

−.618
(.348)

.843
(.298)

Family income (0 to 1)

.015
(.086)

.347
(.106)

.144
(.135)

−.194
(.116)

2004 survey

.240
(.045)

.142
(.055)

Intercept

.502
(.062)

−.352
(.077)

.491
(.094)

.014
(.083)

Log likelihood

−3,024.0

−1,618.0

−1,005.8

−1,374.5

Pseudo-R2

.02

.05

.02

.02

N

2,525

1,976

1,499

1,414

Source: 2002 and 2004 ANES surveys.

a Includes only those respondents who said that the difference in incomes between rich people and poor people has increased.

images

FIGURE 4.2 Perceptions of Increasing Income Differences by Ideology and Information Level

The pattern of ideological polarization in figure 4.2 will appear familiar to readers of John Zaller's influential book The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Zaller's model of opinion formation encompasses situations in which a “mainstream message” produces uniform shifts in opinion among politically aware conservatives and liberals. However, in situations where political elites are ideologically polarized, Zaller's model implies a very different pattern, with politically aware conservatives and liberals pulled in opposite directions by the contrasting arguments of their respective elites. The result is a characteristic diverging pattern, with undifferentiated (and generally moderate) policy preferences among less-aware conservatives and liberals, but increasing ideological disparity among those who are more attentive to elite rhetoric.35

The significance of political awareness in Zaller's model stems from the fact that logical (or merely conventional) connections between broad ideologies and specific policies are not likely to be automatically and identically evident to all conservatives and liberals. Rather, their apprehension requires careful thought—or, more likely, secondhand exposure to careful thought—about specific facts and values in the light of broad ideological commitments. People who are unusually attentive to political discourse and sophisticated in their political thinking are especially likely to grasp those connections.

The difference here is that political awareness produced sharp ideological polarization not just in policy preferences but also in perceptions of a seemingly straightforward, objective fact. Rather than contributing to accurate apprehension of that fact by conservative and liberal observers alike, political awareness seems mostly to have taught people how the political elites who share their ideological commitments would like them to see the world. In particular, what is most significant in figure 4.2 is that the conservatives who were most politically aware were most likely to deny that income differences had increased. In this instance, political awareness did more to facilitate ideological consistency than it did to promote an accurate perception of real social conditions.36

While perceptions of increasing income differences provide a striking example of ideological disparity in the effect of political information, the example is by no means an isolated one. The statistical analysis presented in table 4.10 reveals an even larger ideological disparity in the impact of political information on people's moral assessments of increasing inequality than on their factual perceptions of increasing inequality. Among ideological moderates, the probability of saying that increasing inequality was a bad thing (among those who recognized that inequality had, in fact, increased) ranged from 46% among the least informed to 73% among the best informed. The impact of information among liberals was even greater, with the best informed virtually unanimous in saying that increasing inequality was a bad thing. Among conservatives, however, the impact of political awareness was reversed: the best-informed conservatives were significantly less likely than those who were relatively uninformed to say that an increasing income gap between rich people and poor people was a bad thing.37 Thus, for moral assessments as well as factual perceptions of inequality, the impact of information was strongly conditioned by ideological predispositions.

Figure 4.3 shows how ideology and political information combined to influence the probability that respondents in the ANES surveys would both recognize and regret the growth of economic inequality. Among extreme liberals (represented by the solid line in the figure), that probability increased dramatically with increases in general political awareness. At the bottom of the distribution of information, only about two-thirds of extreme liberals recognized that inequality had increased, and fewer than half of those who recognized an increase said that was a bad thing. (Most of the rest said that they had not thought about whether increasing inequality was good or bad.) However, among the best-informed liberals, more than 95% recognized that inequality had increased, and more than 95% of that 95% said that was a bad thing. In contrast, among extreme conservatives (represented by the dotted line in figure 4.3) the effect of political information was to depress both recognition of growing inequality and opposition to growing inequality. Thus, while the least-informed conservatives were about as likely as the least-informed liberals to recognize and regret growing inequality, only about one in six of the best-informed conservatives did so.

Qualitatively similar interactions between political information and ideology also appear in responses to the other questions included in table 4.10. For example, highly informed liberals were much more likely than uninformed liberals to deny that a poor person has the same chance as a wealthy person of getting a fair trial (96% versus 75%), but highly informed conservatives were slightly less likely than uninformed conservatives to perceive economic bias in the legal system (62% versus 67%).38 An even starker ideological gap appears in assessments of the importance of hard work as an explanation for income differences, which are presented graphically in figure 4.4. At the bottom of the information scale, conservatives and liberals were equally likely to see differences in hard work as a very important source of economic inequality. However, conservatives and liberals at the top of the information scale had vastly different views on this issue: more than 70% of highly informed conservatives, but only 15% of highly informed liberals, considered it very important that “some people just don't work as hard.”39

images

FIGURE 4.3 Probability of Recognizing and Regretting Increasing Income Differences

The patterns of ideological polarization evident in figures 4.2, 4.3, and 4.4 suggest that American beliefs about inequality are profoundly political in their origins and implications. Well-informed conservatives and liberals differ markedly, not only in their normative assessments of increasing inequality, as one might expect, but also in their perceptions of the causes, extent, and consequences of inequality. This is not simply a matter of people with different values drawing different conclusions from a set of agreed-upon facts. Analysts of public opinion in the realm of inequality—as in many other realms—would do well to recognize that the facts themselves are very much subject to ideological dispute. For their part, political actors in the realm of inequality—as in many other realms—would do well to recognize that careful logical arguments running from factual premises to policy conclusions are unlikely to persuade people who are ideologically motivated to distort or deny the facts. While it is certainly true, as Jennifer Hochschild has argued, that “Where You Stand Depends on What You See,” it is equally true that what you are willing to see depends in significant part on where you stand.40

images

FIGURE 4.4 Perceptions That “Some People Just Don't Work as Hard” by Ideology and Information Level

At the same time, it is important to bear in mind that cleavages in beliefs and values are much more muted among relatively uninformed people than among those who pay close attention to politics. In fact, liberals and conservatives in the least-informed stratum of the public are virtually indistinguishable in the analyses reported in table 4.10.41 In the context of factual questions, this apparent consensus across ideological lines may seem reassuring. When it comes to policy preferences, however, agreement between uninformed liberals and conservatives may suggest that people on one side or the other—or both—are failing to recognize the implications of their own values for their views about crucial public issues.

The analyses presented in the next five chapters turn from facts and values to public policies. My aim is to account for how policies are formulated in the American political system of unequal democracy. Chapters 5, 6, and 7 provide detailed case studies of key policies with major ramifications for the economic fortunes of rich, middle-class, and working poor Americans—the Bush tax cuts of 2001 and 2003, the campaign to repeal the estate tax, and the long-term erosion of the federal minimum wage. Chapter 8 provides a much more general analysis of policy-making across a broad range of issues, while chapter 9 focuses on the response of the American political system to the Great Recession following the Wall Street meltdown of 2008.

In examining the role of public opinion in the policy-making process, it will be crucial to consider the ways in which citizens' policy preferences reflect political values and sympathies of the sort examined in this chapter. However, it will be equally important to bear in mind the extent to which many ordinary citizens fail to translate their broad values and sympathies into consistent views about specific policy issues. As we saw in tables 4.2 and 4.4, egalitarian values and sympathies do seem to undergird liberal positions on a variety of important policy issues. But the analyses presented in chapters 5 and 6 will suggest that the political significance of economic inequality is mostly lost on many Americans. Although they may express genuine allegiance to egalitarian values, they are not sufficiently attuned to the political debate to apply their values sensibly and consistently in formulating responses to some of the most important issues in contemporary American politics.

1 Perhaps the most ambitious work along these lines is by Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (2002), though, as I note in chapter 11, their statistical analyses seem to imply smaller direct effects of public opinion on policy and larger electoral effects than one might suppose from their prose.

2 Writing in response to the first wave of enthusiasm for plebiscitary democracy at the turn of the 20th century, A. Lawrence Lowell (1913, 45–46) noted that “no people, however civilized, are capable of forming real opinions on all subjects,” and that “no real public opinion is possible” unless “the essential facts are matters of common knowledge from everyday experience, or where they have been so much discussed that familiarity with them has been generally diffused.”

3 Philip Converse's (1964) essay on “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics” is the single most influential assessment of the coherence and consistency of political opinions. Achen and Bartels (2016, especially chap. 2) summarized the relevant scholarly literature and its implications for democratic responsiveness.

4 Glazer (2003, 111); Robert J. Samuelson, “Indifferent to Inequality?” Newsweek, May 7, 2001, 45.

5 Hochschild (1981, 111, 278); McClosky and Zaller (1984, 63); Feldman (2003).

6 Hochschild (1981, 280); McClosky and Zaller (1984, 177–178).

7 Feldman (1988) provided a detailed discussion of the theoretical pedigree and measurement properties of these items.

8 The three items in table 4.1 inviting respondents to agree with egalitarian sentiments all elicit more egalitarian responses than the three inviting them to disagree with egalitarian sentiments. Are people simply prone to agree with such statements regardless of their content? A comparison of responses to the third and fourth questions, which seem closest to being mirror images of each other, is fairly reassuring on this score: the two questions generated similar distributions of responses, with pluralities of 52–34 and 49–32, respectively, for the egalitarian position.

9 A factor analysis of responses to all six questions produces a strong first factor reflecting support for egalitarian values and a much weaker second factor reflecting a response tendency to agree with all six items regardless of whether they measure agreement or disagreement with the egalitarian position. Since all six items load fairly similarly on the first (substantive) factor (and since the items are balanced between agreement and disagreement), I combine them into a summary scale by simply averaging each respondent's answers to the six questions.

10 “Some people feel the government in Washington should see to it that every person has a job and a good standard of living. Suppose these people are at one end of a scale, at point 1. Others think the government should just let each person get ahead on their own. Suppose these people are at the other end, at point 7. And, of course, some other people have opinions somewhere in between, at points 2, 3, 4, 5, or 6. Where would you place yourself on this scale, or haven't you thought much about this?”

11 “Some people think the government should provide fewer services even in areas such as health and education in order to reduce spending. … Other people feel it is important for the government to provide many more services even if it means an increase in spending. … ”

12 “Some people feel that the government in Washington should make every effort to improve the social and economic position of blacks. … Others feel that the government should not make any special effort to help blacks because they should help themselves… .”

13 “There is much concern about the rapid rise in medical and hospital costs. Some people feel there should be a government insurance plan which would cover all medical and hospital expenses for everyone. … Others feel that all medical expenses should be paid by individuals through private insurance plans like Blue Cross or other company paid plans… .”

14 Partisanship is measured using the standard ANES seven-point party identification scale. Ideology is measured by self-placement on a seven-point liberal-conservative scale, with respondents who said that they didn't know or “haven't thought much about” their position (about 28% of the sample) reclassified as moderates. For comparability with the egalitarian values scale, both measures are recoded to range from −1 to +1.

15 The average values on the 1 (conservative) to 7 (liberal) policy scales are 3.51 for aid to blacks, 3.66 for government jobs, 4.15 for government services, and 4.17 for health insurance. The corresponding averages setting the effects of egalitarian values in the bottom panel of table 4.2 to zero would be 3.22 for aid to blacks, 3.40 for government jobs, 3.96 for government services, and 4.02 for health insurance.

16 Verba and Orren (1985, 2).

17 The classic statement of this point is by Converse (1964). Nelson and Kinder (1996) examined how the “group-centrism” of issue preferences can be promoted or inhibited by variations in how issues are framed.

18 The tax burden questions were each asked twice in the 2002 ANES survey, before and after the election. The pre-election responses are reported in table 4.5, since they seem less likely to be affected by sensitization stemming from the extensive battery of questions focusing on inequality and tax policy in the 2002 ANES survey.

19 “The Rich, the Poor and the Growing Gap Between Them,” The Economist, June 17, 2006, 28.

20 Kluegel and Smith (1986); McCall (2013).

21 Lippmann (1922, 10).

22 McCall (2005, 8).

23 Hochschild (1981, 279, 278, 283).

24 Respondents were also asked an open-ended version of the same question. Half were asked the fixed-choice questions in the pre-election survey and the open-ended version in the post-election survey; the other half got the open-ended version first and the fixed-choice questions in the post-election survey. The responses to the fixed-choice questions from the two random half-samples were generally similar, except that those who responded in the post-election survey attached somewhat less importance to “government policies”—despite the fact that the intervening survey content called attention to a variety of relevant government tax and spending policies.

25 Osberg and Smeeding (2003, tables 2.1 and 4.2–1).

26 For example, in a 1998 Gallup poll focusing on “Perceptions of Fairness and Opportunity,” 52% of the respondents with household incomes below $15,000 and 51% of those who described themselves as “have-nots” nevertheless said that “the economic situation in the United States is basically fair.” Jost et al. (2003, 55–56, 58, 60). See also Lerner (1980); Jost and Banaji (1994).

27 Jost et al. (2003, 63). On personality and political ideology more generally, see McClosky (1958) and Stenner (2005).

28 These probabilities represent response tendencies for extreme conservatives and extreme liberals with median incomes, and they split the difference in responses between people interviewed in 2002 and 2004.

29 Jost et al. (2003, 63).

30 For evidence regarding the validity of the interviewers’ assessments of respondents’ political information, see Zaller (1985). For respondents interviewed both before and after the 2002 election, I averaged the ratings provided (almost always by different interviewers) at the end of the pre-election and post-election interviews. For respondents who were not reinterviewed after the election (11% of the sample in 2002 and 12% in 2004), I used the pre-election interviewers’ ratings only. In every case, I calibrated the resulting information scale to reflect each respondent's position in the overall distribution of political information, from zero (for the least informed) to one (for the most informed). The actual range is from .014 to .999.

31 These percentage differences are calculated for ideological moderates with average incomes. Since the statistical results presented in table 4.10 provide strong evidence of interactions between political information and ideology, the effects of information among liberals and conservatives are quite different from those reported here. These differences are highlighted in figures 4.2, 4.3, and 4.4.

32 Better-informed people also provided systematically different explanations for economic inequality, stressing social causes (inequality in educational opportunities, discrimination, and government policies) more heavily than less-informed people did. They were also somewhat less likely to say that rich people are asked to pay too much in taxes—but no more or less likely to say that poor people are asked to pay too much or that they are asked to pay too much. Nor were they more or less likely to think that corporate accounting scandals are widespread. As for perceptions of the partisan politics of inequality, they were much more likely to recognize the differences in positions of the Democratic and Republican Parties on specific tax policies and much more likely to say that the Republicans are “generally better for rich people” and that the Democrats are “generally better for poor people.”

33 Among ideological moderates, recognition of the growing income gap increased less dramatically than among liberals, but still significantly: from 74% at the lowest information level to 84% at the highest information level.

34 For extreme conservatives, the information effect implied by the probit analysis is −.606 (with a standard error of .192); for extreme liberals, the effect is +1.336 (with a standard error of .235).

35 Zaller (1992, chaps. 6 and 9).

36 Christopher Achen and I have developed a mathematical model of political inference in which political awareness increases the weight attached to both partisan predispositions and reality in the construction of political judgments (Achen and Bartels 2006). Insofar as the former effect dominates the latter effect, this model implies not only that partisan disparities in political judgment will be concentrated among people who are high in political awareness, as in Zaller's model, but also that people who are generally better informed about politics may be most inaccurate in their political perceptions. Danielle Shani (2006) has presented a good deal of empirical evidence suggesting that partisan biases in perceptions of political conditions are exacerbated by political information. On partisan biases in perceptions more generally, see Bartels (2002a).

37 For extreme conservatives, the information effect implied by the probit analysis is −.566 (with a standard error of .245); for extreme liberals, the effect is +2.022 (with a standard error of .306).

38 The implied information effects in the probit analysis are +1.088 (with a standard error of .421) for extreme liberals and −.149 (with a standard error of .344) for extreme conservatives.

39 The implied information effects in the probit analysis are +.693 (with a standard error of .309) for extreme conservatives and −.993 (with a standard error of .347) for extreme liberals.

40 Hochschild (2001); Hochschild and Einstein (2015).

41 The one instance in table 4.10 in which the main effect of ideology (that is, the effect of ideology among people at the bottom of the distribution of political information) is large enough to be reliably distinguishable from zero is for the factual question about increasing differences in incomes—and that effect suggests, quite implausibly, that uninformed conservatives were more likely than uninformed liberals to recognize that incomes had become more unequal. I suspect that this anomalous result reflects some non-linearity in the effect of political information that is not adequately captured by the simple statistical specification reported in the table.