8

Macro Matters: The Real Economy

Companies operate in a larger economy, sometimes just domestic and often global, and the assumptions we make about macroeconomic variables affect the valuations of all companies. This chapter begins by looking at how changes in the real economy, inflation, and exchange rates affect valuation. It also looks at the historical behavior of each of these variables. With each of these variables, we also examine how analysts deal (or avoid dealing) with them, in the course of valuing companies. They often make implicit assumptions about growth and inflation that might be unrealistic or explicit assumptions that are internally inconsistent. We evaluate whether we should be building in views on the macroeconomic variables and, if so, how best to do this.

Growth in the Real Economy

Every business is affected by the state of the economy, although the magnitude of the effect might vary across businesses. This section looks at how the growth in the real economy affects inputs into the valuation of individual companies. It also goes into some history on real economic growth.

Why Does Real Economic Growth Matter?

When valuing companies, we have to estimate growth in revenues, income, and cash flows over time. Although we tend to look at the company’s specific prospects while making these estimates, a company’s operating numbers are influenced by the state of the economy in which the company operates. Put more simply, the revenues and earnings numbers look much better if the economy is doing well than if it is slowing down or shrinking. Because we are forecasting these numbers for the future, our estimates for individual companies are affected by how well or badly we think the economy will do over the next few years.

Although all companies might be affected by the growth rate of the economy, they are not affected to the same extent. We expect companies in cyclical businesses, such as housing and automobiles, to be affected more by overall economic growth. Conversely, companies that produce staples should be affected to a lesser extent by whether the economy is in boom or recession mode. Consequently, optimism about future economic growth will result in higher values for the former, relative to the latter. The effect of changes in economic growth on company valuations can also vary, depending on whether they derive their value primarily from existing assets or growth assets. Not surprisingly, companies with significant growth assets see their values change much more dramatically in response to shifts in the overall economy than mature companies.

Finally, economic growth affects other key market-related inputs into valuation. In Chapter 6, “A Shaky Base: a ‘Risky’ Risk-Free Rate,” we noted that risk-free rates tend to change over time and that change is often related to real economic growth. When economies are growing briskly, risk-free rates tend to rise, whereas economic slowdowns are associated with lower interest rates. In Chapter 7, “Risky Ventures: Assessing the Price of Risk,” we traced the shifts in equity risk premiums and default spreads over time. We noted their tendency to rise with uncertainty about the economy and investor risk aversion.

Looking at History

How much does real economic growth change from year to year? The answer clearly depends on which economy we look at. The first part of this section focuses on real economic growth in the U.S. over time and shows how both real and nominal growth have varied across time. We will also look at how real economic growth has affected the aggregate earnings and dividends of publicly traded firms. In the second part of the section, we will expand the discussion to encompass other countries, including the fast-growing emerging markets of Asia and Latin America.

U.S. Real Economic Growth Over Time

During the 20th century, the U.S. grew to become the dominant global economic power, but the growth was not uninterrupted. Extended periods of economic decline and stagnation occurred, with the Great Depression being the most significant example. Figure 8.1 summarizes annual changes in real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the U.S. from 1929 to 2016.

A combination graph presents the data related to U.S. Real Economic Growth over the period 1928 to 2016.

Figure 8.1 U.S. Real Economic Growth Over Time: 1929 to 2016

The shaded areas in the figure represent recessions, at least as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). Two consecutive quarters of negative economic growth in real GDP has become the rule of thumb for classifying recessions. Table 8.1 summarizes the business cycles since 1945 in the U.S., with the length of each cycle in months.

Table 8.1 U.S. Recessions (in months): 1945-2016

Start of Recession

End of Recession

Length of Recession (in months)

Mar-45

Oct-45

7

Dec-48

Oct-49

11

Aug-53

May-54

10

Sep-57

Apr-58

8

May-60

Feb-61

9

Jan-70

Nov-70

11

Dec-73

Mar-75

16

Aug-81

Nov-82

16

Aug-08

Feb-09

7

Mar-01

Nov-01

8

Jan-08

Jun-09

18

Average

 

11

Median

 

10

High

 

18

Low

 

7

Source: FRED

Looking at this long time period of history, some interesting facts emerge that might have implications for how we deal with real growth in valuation:

If we accept the proposition that predicting economic cycles is impossible and that we should focus on estimating real growth over the next five or ten years rather than the growth in the next quarter, our task becomes easier (at least in hindsight). Figure 8.1 includes a smoothed-out estimate of real growth over the next five years and the next ten years to provide a contrast to the year-to-year real-growth numbers. The ten-year growth rate estimated in 1954, for instance, is the average growth rate from 1954 to 1963. Note that these long-term forecasts have far more stability, especially since World War II. Both the five-year and ten-year average growth rates have been between 2% and 3%. This stability suggests that using a reasonable real-growth rate number for the long term is more important (and viable) than forecasting growth on a year-to-year basis.

Real growth affects valuation through the earnings and cash flows reported by businesses. Therefore, Figure 8.2 shows how aggregate earnings and dividends on the S&P 500 have behaved over time, as real economic growth has varied.

A combination graph presents the data related to Earnings and Dividends on S and P 500 Companies over the period 1928 to 2016.

Figure 8.2 Earnings and Dividends on S&P 500 Companies

Looking back at the last 80 years of earnings and dividends on the S&P 500 companies, three trends emerge. The first is that both earnings and dividends are sensitive to economic conditions, with both declining during recessions. The second is that earnings are much more volatile than dividends over time. The third is that although earnings growth is loosely correlated with real economic growth, the two are not always in sync, with low (high) earnings growth in some periods of high (low) real growth, reflecting both lags between economies and business operations as well as the globalization of companies. For instance, earnings growth at U.S. companies has been robust between 2009 and 2016, notwithstanding slow growth in the U.S. economy, partly because U.S. companies derive so much of their revenues overseas.

As a final test, Figure 8.3 shows how the level of the S&P 500 index has changed over time as a function of real economic growth.

A trend graph comparing the Percent Real GDP growth and Percent Change in Stock prices.

Figure 8.3 Real Economic Growth and the S&P 500

Looking at the changes in real GDP growth and changes in the S&P 500, it seems clear that the index is far more volatile than the economy. Another interesting and more subtle relationship is also visible for most of the graph. Stock prices seem to drop prior to the slowing down in the real economy and seem to start their rise prior to the actual recovery taking hold.

Differences in Real Growth Across Countries

Estimating both short-term and long-term real growth in a mature market like the U.S. is far simpler than forecasting growth in young economies, especially ones that derive much of their growth from a commodity or specific sector. The fact that these economies are small, relative to the global economy, can allow them to grow at double-digit rates in good years and suffer catastrophic drops in bad years. Figure 8.4 summarizes real-growth rates for four time periods: 1997–2001, 2002–2006, 2007–2011, and 2012–2016 in Brazil, India, China, and Russia and contrasts them with real-growth rates in the European Union (EU) countries, Japan, and the U.S.

A vertical bar graph presents data related to Real-Growth Rates in GDP across seven different countries.

Figure 8.4 Real-Growth Rates in GDP Across Countries

Not only are real-growth rates higher in the smaller, emerging markets than in the mature economies, but they also tend to be volatile. Among the BRIC countries, China clearly dominates in real growth over the period, whereas Russia lags. Among the developed countries, Japan has had the lowest real growth rate over this time period and the Euro zone has seen real growth decline in the last decade. It should come as no surprise that developed market companies increasingly look to emerging markets, in general, and China, in particular, to recapture their growth potential.

The Dark Side

In their zeal to incorporate the effects of real growth and views on how that real growth affects the values of companies, analysts are often tempted to overreach. In particular, three practices in valuation, related to real economic growth, can give rise to skewed end numbers:

In summary, when analysts are asked to value companies, it is best that they don’t become economic forecasters, partly because it will distract them from doing their company-specific homework, but also because the history of macroeconomic forecasting is not filled with success.

The Light Side

So, how should we deal with real economic growth in valuations? The answer is to do less, rather than more, and focus on the company, not the economy. Specifically, the following are good practices to adopt:

The bottom line again is a simple one. If your job is assessing the value of a company, the more time you spend obsessing about economic growth and researching the economy, the less time you are spending on understanding your company and valuing it well.

Expected Inflation

The valuation of every company will be affected by the assumptions we make about expected inflation in the future. This section begins by looking at why inflation has such an impact on value, how inflation rates have behaved in the past, and how much and why inflation rates vary across currencies.

Why Does Expected Inflation Matter?

As we noted in Chapter 6, valuations can be either nominal or real. If they are nominal, the expected inflation rate is built into both the cash flows and the discount rate. In nominal valuations, expected inflation affects key inputs that we use in our analysis:

In other words, changing the expected inflation rate affects all aspects of a nominal valuation. That is why the currency in which we do a nominal valuation matters: expected inflation rates can vary widely across different currencies. Figure 8.5 shows the interrelationship between inflation, currency choice, and other valuation inputs.

A figure shows the interdependence between Currency choice, Inflation, and Value of asset.

Figure 8.5 Currency Choice, Inflation, and Value

In a real valuation, neither the cash flows nor the discount rate has an expected inflation component, and real growth has to come from growth in real output. One reason analysts choose to do real valuations is to try to immunize them from changes in inflation. However, expectations about inflation and changes in those expectations can affect even real valuations for the following reasons:

In summary, the value that we arrive at for a company, if we believe that expected inflation will be 3%, might be very different from the value of that same company with an expected inflation rate of 5%. Inflation is not a neutral item in valuation and changing inflation can have value consequences.

Expected inflation affects risk-free rate and equity risk premiums, two inputs covered in the preceding two chapters. When expected inflation increases, the risk-free rate increases to reflect that expectation, and equity risk premiums might be ramped up as well. Uncertainty about inflation in the future can also make companies more reluctant to invest in long-term projects and thus alter both the level of real economic growth and what sectors it occurs in. Finally, if the expected inflation rate in one currency increases relative to other currencies, we should expect exchange rates to follow, with the higher inflation currency depreciating over time.

Looking at History

If expected inflation rates are constant, incorporating their effect into value is relatively simple. It is because inflation rates change over time and vary across currencies that they can wreak havoc on valuation. This section begins by looking at variation in the inflation rate in the U.S. dollar over time. Then it examines differences in inflation rates across currencies.

U.S. Inflation Rate Across Time

Before we look at variation in the inflation rate across time, we must determine how inflation is to be measured. The task is a complicated one, especially when we look at an economy as large and complex as the U.S. At least in theory, the inflation rate should measure changes in how much it costs to buy a representative basket of goods and services from period to period. Not surprisingly, inflation rates vary depending on what we put in the basket. The U.S. has three widely used measures of inflation, with a long history attached to each:

All three measures share some common problems. The first is that the basket of goods and services that is used to compute inflation is kept stable even as relative prices change. In other words, it is assumed that the proportion of the basket that is oil remains the same, even if oil prices increase significantly relative to other items in the basket. In reality, though, consumers use less gasoline and adjust their consumption to reflect relative prices. The second problem with the basket is that it does not consider implicit costs. For instance, the cost of housing is measured by looking at the cost of renting a house rather than the implicit cost of owning one. To the extent that housing prices are increasing much faster than rental costs are, as was the case between 2002 and 2006, inflation will be understated. Figure 8.6 graphs the behavior of all three measures of inflation from 1921 to 2016.

A trend graph captures the inflation rates in the U.S.

Figure 8.6 Inflation Rates in the U.S.

Note that notwithstanding the differences, the three measures move together over time. Quirks in how they are computed have sometimes caused one measure to lag the other. During much of this period, inflation in the U.S. was benign and ranged from 1% to 4%. Bouts of high inflation occurred in the 1930s and during World War II, but the volatility in inflation accelerated in the 1970s, with inflation rates hitting double digits by the last few years of the decade. The only sustained period of deflation was during the Great Depression, when prices dropped more than 10% a year in 1932 and 1933. Since the 2008 financial crisis, the U.S. has flirted with deflation in a couple of years and the average inflation rate has been low.

All three measures of inflation shown in Figure 8.6 represent actual inflation. In much of valuation, our focus is on expected inflation. Two measures try to capture expectations. One comes from surveys done by the University of Michigan on inflation expectations among consumers. The other can be backed out of the ten-year nominal and inflation-indexed Treasury bond rates:

Expected Inflation Rate=(1+Nominal Treasury Rate)(1+Inflation Indexed Treasury Rate)1

Figure 8.7 graphs both measures since 2003, when the inflation-indexed Treasury bond starting trading.

A vertical bar graph compares the Expected Inflation based on Consumer Surveys and Treasury Rates.

Figure 8.7 Expected Inflation: Consumer Surveys and Treasury Rates

The survey numbers and the Treasury-imputed inflation rate closely track the historical inflation numbers. The expected inflation rates backed out of the Treasury rates have been consistently lower than survey expectations but have been better predictors of actual inflation during the periods.

Inflation, Earnings, and Stock Prices

As we noted at the beginning of this section, expected inflation is relevant in valuation because earnings and dividends can be affected by changes in inflation rates. To examine this relationship, Figure 8.8 shows changes in the aggregate earnings on the S&P 500 against the inflation rate (measured using the CPI) over time.

A combination graph shows the Earnings and Inflation in the U.S.

Figure 8.8 Earnings and Inflation in the U.S.

Note that although nominal earnings have increased at higher rates during periods of high inflation, there is substantial noise in the relationship, especially in the years when inflation is changing. Between 1971 and 1980, for instance, the average inflation rate was 8.19%, but earnings increased at a compounded annual rate of 10.57% during the period and earnings growth in the early part of the decade did not keep up with inflation. This resulted in a real-growth rate in earnings of just under 2.5%. Between 1981 and 1990, the inflation rate dropped to 4.47%, and the nominal earnings growth rate was also lower at 4.74%, yielding a barely positive real-growth rate in earnings. In the period since 2008, the relationship between earnings growth and inflation has become even weaker, indicating again that globalization is having an effect.

The higher earnings growth posted by companies during periods of high inflation might seem to indicate that high inflation is good for stock prices and values. To help us examine whether this is, in fact, the case, Figure 8.9 shows the relationship between inflation and changes in the level of the S&P 500 index from 1928 to 2016.

A combination graph shows the Stock Prices and Inflation in the U.S.

Figure 8.9 Stock Prices and Inflation in the U.S.

It is difficult to see any pattern here when it comes to stock prices. The S&P 500 increased only about 10% a year during the 1970s, when earnings growth was healthy, whereas the annual return was closer to 16% between 1981 and 1990, when inflation was lower. The complicated relationship between inflation and value should come as no surprise, because inflation is a double-edged sword. Higher inflation might allow companies to increase earnings much more quickly, but interest rates and discount rates also go up—nullifying and, in some cases, overwhelming the effects of higher earnings.

Inflation Rates Across Currencies

The only reason that the currency you do a valuation in matters is because inflation rates vary across currencies. In trying to compare actual inflation rates in different currencies, we run into two issues. The first is that the way inflation is measured varies widely across countries, making it difficult to compare them head to head. The second is that many countries have government-imposed price ceilings for some products and services, and these fixed prices can skew inflation measures.

In spite of these estimation issues, comparing inflation rates in different currencies is still useful. Figure 8.10 shows actual inflation rates in 2015 and 2016 and the expected inflation rates for 2017 for seven currencies.

A vertical bar graph depicts the data related to Inflation Rates in Different Currencies.

Figure 8.10 Inflation Rates in Different Currencies

Note that inflation rates were highest in Russia and Brazil, moderate in India and Mexico, and low in the U.S., the Euro zone, and Japan during this period. In fact, Japan had deflation in 2016 and it stands to reason that interest rates are also lowest in Japan and highest in Brazil and Russia and that exchange rates reflect the differences in inflation.

The Dark Side

The ways in which analysts make mistakes with inflation are different in different parts of the world, largely as a result of their inflation histories. In countries with a history of high or even hyperinflation, analysts often spend too much time trying to get inflation right in valuation, and in countries with a history of low and stable inflation, analysts often forget all about inflation. Looking across both groups, here is a list of inflation sins:

Ironically, the more work that analysts do in trying to forecast inflation correctly and get that number into their valuations, the more damage they risk doing to their valuations.

The Light Side

The remedies for inflation problems in valuation mirror those given for real economic growth. Less is more, with the following guiding principles:

If you are still concerned about inflation expectations and how it is affecting your valuation, we have a simple suggestion. Value a company with explicit assumptions about inflation driving your discount rate, cash flow, and growth inputs and check the value. Then change the inflation rate and work through the effect on each of your inputs and then on value. You will notice that if you are consistent, the effects of inflation on value are far smaller than you might have expected. That insight will free you to spend more time on the inputs that truly matter, and less on estimating or forecasting inflation for the future.

Exchange Rates

As with real economic growth and inflation rates, our views on exchange rates can affect the value that we attach to individual companies. In this section, we will first consider why exchange rates matter, and then we will examine practices in valuation, related to exchange rates, that can pull them off course.

Why Do Exchange Rates Matter?

Changes in exchange rates in the past and expectations in the future can make a difference in valuation. For companies with foreign operations, the reported earnings are affected by changes in exchange rates. Favorable movements in exchange rates result in higher earnings, whereas unfavorable movements can result in large losses. Note, though, that what type of movement is favorable or unfavorable depends on the nature of the foreign exposure. If the firm’s costs are all domestic and its revenues are overseas, a weakening of the domestic currency causes earnings to improve. On the other hand, if the firm’s costs are overseas but its revenues are primarily domestic, as is the case for some software companies, a weakening in the domestic currency causes earnings to deteriorate. Expectations of future changes in exchange rates also manifest themselves in differences in expected growth. Thus, the company with foreign revenues gets a boost in growth if we expect the domestic currency to continue to depreciate over time. On the other hand, the growth rate for the company with foreign costs might have to be scaled back for the same expectation. Views on exchange rates can affect even companies with just domestic operations, because their competitive advantages against foreign adversaries will be affected by expectations of exchange rates. If we expect the domestic currency to weaken, a foreign company will be at a disadvantage relative to a purely domestic company. This, in turn, will affect expectations of future growth, margins, and returns for the domestic company.

In emerging markets, views on exchange rates can sometimes play an outsized role, because analysts choose to value emerging-market companies in a foreign currency to make some of their estimation easier. Thus, many Latin American companies are valued in U.S. dollars, because estimating risk-free rates and risk premiums is easier to do than in the local currency. However, this also requires that the future cash flows for these companies be estimated in U.S. dollars, even though the actual cash flows might be in pesos or reais. The conversion of the local currency cash flows to U.S. dollar cash flows requires expected exchange rates (local currency to U.S. dollars) in the future.

Exchange rate views and expectations can affect valuations in one final way. In the face of volatile exchange rates, some companies choose to hedge their currency exposures, leading to hedging costs that lower operating income and value. Other companies, however, make bets on exchange rate movements. If these bets turn out to be right, they add substantially to profits, but if they are wrong, they can cause huge losses. To value a company, we therefore need information on its hedging and speculative bets on the future direction of exchange rates. That information is not always forthcoming.

Looking at History

Until 1971, the world operated in a regime of fixed exchange rates. Changes occurred only when governments chose to devalue or revalue a currency. Because these fixed exchange rates were often incompatible with the underlying fundamentals (inflation, interest rates, and real growth in the economies), black markets sprang up for the most overvalued and undervalued currencies where the exchange rates were very different from the official rates. After the Bretton Woods Conference in 1971, the major currencies were allowed to float (and find a market price), but most emerging markets continued (and some still continue) to maintain a fixed rate structure.

The currencies that have the longest market history are the U.S. dollar, the British pound, the Swiss franc, and the Japanese yen. Figure 8.11 graphs the movements in those currencies, with the dollar as the base as well as a trade-weighted dollar, against major currencies.

A trend graph captures the comparison of major trading currencies to the U.S. Dollar.

Figure 8.11 Major Trading Currencies versus the U.S. Dollar

Note that a rising value indicates that the currency has strengthened against the dollar, as is the case with the Swiss franc and the Japanese yen, and a declining value is an indication of the currency weakening against the U.S. dollar, as is the case with the British pound. There are two things to note. The first is that different currencies often move in different directions. During this period, the dollar strengthened against the pound but weakened substantially against both the Swiss franc and the yen. Within each currency, there are long cycles of up and down movements. With the Swiss franc, for instance, the dollar weakened through 1980, strengthened for the first half of the 1980s, and reverted to weakness in the second half of the decade. Some of this movement can be traced to the underlying economic fundamentals—the strengthening of the yen reflects Japan’s rise as an economic power during the 1970s and 1980s—but some of it reflects deliberate government policy. The U.S. actively encouraged dollar depreciation after 2001 to improve the competitive position of U.S. companies in the export market. Since 2008, there have been extended periods of strengthening and weakening in the currency, often with no fundamental reasons.

Figure 8.12 shows the U.S. dollar versus the euro, which replaced the individual EU currencies (such as the French franc and the Deutsche mark) in 1999.

A trend graph shows the comparison of Euro to U.S. Dollar.

Figure 8.12 The Euro versus the U.S. Dollar

After the euro was introduced in January 1999, it initially suffered depreciation, reaching a value of $0.85/euro in June, but it has gone through an extended period of appreciation against the U.S. dollar. The high was just over $1.575/euro in April 2008 but the last decade has seen the rate drop to $1.05/euro in December 2016 before it strengthened again in 2017.

Some emerging-market currencies have opened up to free-market pricing over the last two decades. They have been much more volatile than the developed-market currencies shown in Figures 8.11 and 8.12. Figure 8.13 graphs the Mexican peso, Indian rupee, the Brazilian real, and the Chinese yuan from 1995 to 2017.

A trend graph shows the comparison of emerging market currencies to the U.S. Dollar.

Figure 8.13 Emerging-Market Currencies versus the U.S. Dollar

The Brazilian real lost almost 80% of its value against the dollar between 1995 and 2002 but more than doubled its value between 2002 and early 2008. In the 2012–2015 time period, it reversed direction and lost almost half its value against the dollar, before stabilizing in 2016 and 2017. The volatility in these rates should not come as a surprise. The short-term movements are caused by political instability in these markets and economic variability over time. The long-term movements of these currencies, though, are more reflective of differences in inflation, with the rupee, peso, and Brazilian real all losing half or more of their value against the dollar between 1995 and 2017, whereas the Yuan strengthened against the dollar over that same period.

Although the conventional wisdom is that the currencies of mature economies like the U.S., Japan, and Western Europe (with similar inflation) do not go through sharp contortions, the market crisis of 2008 that we highlighted in the preceding chapter might lead to a rethinking. Figure 8.14 shows the movements in the U.S. dollar versus the euro, yen, and Brazilian real from September 12 to October 16.

A trend graph depicts the Exchange rates during a Market Crisis with respect to U.S. Dollar.

Figure 8.14 Exchange Rates During a Market Crisis

Although the volatility in the Brazilian real might be predictable, the sharp devaluation of the euro (which has lost almost 8% of its value against the dollar) and the rise in the yen (up about 10%) is a sign that volatility in exchange rates is not restricted to emerging-market currencies.

The Dark Side

A few decades ago, when most companies derived much or all of their revenues domestically, analysts avoided thinking about or dealing with exchange rates. Those days are behind us, because most companies generate some or much of their revenues from foreign markets, and even those that do not have costs in other currencies. Thus, currency avoidance is no longer an option, because movements in exchange rates can affect revenue growth, operating margins, and even discount rates. Unfortunately, the way analysts deal with exchange rates exposes them to valuation mistakes, with the following practices contributing to the errors:

As our forecasting tools get more sophisticated and data gets more plentiful, falling into the trap of believing that you can forecast exchange rates and bringing them into your valuations is easy to do. If your mission is to value companies, not play pricing games with exchange rates, you will be undercutting that mission, if you make yourself an exchange rate forecaster.

The Light Side

Keeping their views on exchange rate out of their individual company valuations is often difficult for analysts. To prevent these views from hijacking valuations, we suggest that you follow a few simple rules:

You might want to consider using one final tool in dealing with macroeconomic variables. If your company is particularly exposed to macroeconomic movements (in real growth, inflation, or exchange rates), you could use probability distributions for these variables and value your company using simulations. Thus, rather than value a cyclical company with a point estimate of real economic growth, you could be more realistic and come up with a distribution of value for your company, given a distribution for real economic growth.

Conclusion

The value of every company is affected by what we expect to happen to the overall economy, expected inflation, and exchange rates in the future. Given this centrality, it is surprising how haphazard analysts are when it comes to making reasonable assumptions about these variables. Some make implicit assumptions through the company-specific numbers they use and are unable or unwilling to make these assumptions explicit. Others build all their forecasts on last year’s numbers, thus building whatever happened last year with the real economy, inflation, and exchange rates into their future estimates and value. Still others make strong assumptions about the future path of macroeconomic variables, and through these assumptions have large effects on value.

As you review the chapter, you should be seeing a pattern. With real economic growth, inflation rates, and exchange rates, there are two suggestions for dealing with all of them. First, no matter how strongly you feel about future movements in these variables, you should avoid bringing those views into company valuations. You can use your macro views to make judgments on whether you should invest in equities, which sectors to invest in, and what geographies to concentrate on, as part of the asset allocation process. Second, macro variables affect all of your valuation inputs; that is, growth, cash flows, and discount rates, and being internally consistent is more important than being right on these variables.

___________________________

1. Assume that a firm has $100 million in EBITDA, $40 million in depreciation, and no interest expenses. Furthermore, it faces a marginal tax rate of 40% on its income. The firm reports $36 million in net income and $76 million in cash flows prior to reinvestment (net income + depreciation). Now introduce an inflation rate of 10% into the analysis, and assume that the firm can raise the prices of its products at the inflation rate. EBITDA rises to $110 million, but depreciation stays frozen at $40 million. The firm now reports net income of $42 million and cash flows of $82 million. If we convert the latter into real numbers, the real EBITDA is $100 million, the real net income is $37.8 million, and the real cash flow is $73.8 million—$2.2 million less than it used to be.