Chapter 4
The Federal Reserve Prints Our Money (Stop the Presses!)
We have come to a critical juncture in the United States where the budget deficits are so big as to overwhelm our ordinary sources of borrowing money. The answer to making ends meet is so obvious as to seem impossible: The Federal Reserve, as owner of our currency, can print up new money, diluting the purchasing power of all the rest of the currency, to fill the void. This process is as simple as I just explained it, but it’s quite a bit more complex when reviewing the details and the process of all the parties. This chapter lays out that detail for those who want to watch and understand the structure.
The process seems clouded in mystery, almost as if a screen has been purposely stretched over the inner workings, so that we are left thinking that the leaders who are running the machinery of our financial system have special powers to control the nation’s economic systems, wreaking havoc or bringing blessings. It’s really not that mysterious, and once you understand the games that are being played, you will be able to see a few steps ahead what is likely to unfold in our plot of the economic shifts in the coming decade.

What Is the Fed? A Private Profiteer or a Government Agency?

Everybody knows the Federal Reserve is extremely important, and the financial press looks for every clue to determine what Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke’s next step will be to manipulate our money system.
The institution carries far more reverence than it deserves. Former Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan has been called the maestro and the second most powerful man in the western world. Bernanke, the current chairman, hasn’t quite captured the aura of the wizard, but his actions are certainly impacting our financial system. It’s important to understand the responsibilities and the now-expanding actions of this almost 100-year-old institution as it usurps even greater power to control our financial future.
It may be hard to imagine that our country did just fine when we had no central bank. We had no central bank for a half century before the inauguration of the Federal Reserve by an act of Congress on the night before Christmas, 1913 when no one was watching. We see their imprint today on our paper dollars. Dollar bills are officially identified as Federal Reserve Notes because they are issued by the Federal Reserve, fashioned something like a note to borrow. The Federal Reserve issues the Federal Reserve Notes as a liability on its balance sheet, which is held against assets that were composed mostly of treasuries of the federal government.
The Federal Reserve, in its initial days, held gold as backing for the currency. It still holds title to 262 million ounces of gold, which at today’s price (at the time of this writing) of $1,000 an ounce is a substantial $262 billion.
The official duties of the Federal Reserve (as described by its own document www.federalreserve.gov/pf/pdf/pf_1.pdf ) fall into four general areas:
1. Conducting the nation’s monetary policy by influencing the monetary and credit conditions in the economy in pursuit of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.
2. Supervising and regulating banking institutions to ensure the safety and soundness of the nation’s banking and financial system and to protect the credit rights of consumers.
3. Maintaining the stability of the financial system and containing systemic risk that may arise in financial markets.
4. Providing financial services to depository institutions, the U.S. government, and foreign official institutions, including playing a major role in operating the nation’s payments system.
We watch the Federal Reserve’s influence on the markets primarily through its setting of the short-term overnight interest rate on money loaned between banks. This Fed funds rate becomes an indicator for setting many other rates. The rate is set by operations in the open market through its Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). The committee meets about every six weeks to decide whether to raise or lower this key interest rate, and with much fanfare, the FMOC publicizes its current target.
The actual rate can be different from the target, but the Federal Reserve will intervene to drive the rate higher or lower to achieve its announced target. A decade ago, the Federal Reserve didn’t even announce what its target was, hiding behind the screen so that market participants would have to assess from the Federal Reserve actions what the Fed’s policy target rate was. We now sit at the unusual situation of the Federal Reserve having lowered its interest rate to an official range of between 0 percent and a quarter of a percent, with the idea that low rates should help stimulate the economy, allow for loans to be provided at relatively low rates so that businesses and consumers will borrow to spend, and generally expand economic growth. The rate has never been lower.
The United States banking system has been called a Fractional Reserve System because the regular commercial banks (which create our personal checking accounts and give us mortgages for our houses) are required to keep only a fraction of their deposits on reserve at the Federal Reserve to back up their deposits. The rest they can loan out to make profits.
In the original design of the system, the fraction of deposits required to be placed with the Federal Reserve—called the reserve requirement—was an important policy tool to expand and contract the ability of banks to make new loans and thereby multiply the amount of credit and deposits throughout the system. The reserve requirement percentage has been decreased, and the kind of funds against which reserves are required then also decreased, so that currently we are in a situation where there is in effect almost no requirement for banks to have reserves at the Fed. Although the requirement structurally exists, the dollar amounts are so small as to have little effect on the operations of banks. Basically, commercial banks run into other limitations (such as their capital adequacy) before they are limited as to how much they can loan out. Consequently, since this policy tool is no longer effective it is rarely discussed.
The legal structure of the Federal Reserve is often debated as to whether it is a private entity with independence from the federal government or if it is really a branch of the financial operations of the federal government. There are 12 branches of the Federal Reserve Bank scattered across the regions of the country, and the board of governors operates out of Washington, DC.
Key leaders and presidents are appointed by the President and confirmed by Congress. Legally, the Federal Reserve exists as an independent corporation whose shares are owned by commercial banks which are members of the Federal Reserve System. Mainly, that means there are shares held by the large banks of the country. These shares pay a modest dividend, but in comparison to other flows, the influence of the shareholders is nonexistent.
While the legal structure exists for independence, the reality is that the Federal Reserve is very much at the center of the policymaking activities of the federal government by coordination with the Treasury. There should be no mistake that the Federal Reserve is not an independent entity. It is a branch of the policymaking and implementation aspects of our financial system as directed in coordination with the federal government.
Their other main constituents are the commercial banks of the United States, which they are charged with supporting and regulating. The investment banks (which deal with issuing corporate shares) were not directly regulated by the Federal Reserve, but in the financial crisis of 2008-09 almost all investment banks of any size converted themselves into bank holding companies. That structure allows investment banking and commercial banking to coexist under the same corporate structure, so that there are virtually no important investment banks that are beyond the reach of Federal Reserve regulation. The investment banks converted to give them access to the rescue funds available to banks regulated by the Fed.
The important point of this discussion of bank regulation is to notice that the Federal Reserve acts to support the banking system in its primary role as the banker’s bank, to ensure the strength and viability of all banks in the United States. So the Fed has a separate loyalty to the banks.

Who Benefits from the Fed?

The dictum “Follow the money!” involves determining for whom the Federal Reserve works. Most people don’t realize that the Fed is a private corporation that made a profit of about $45 billion last year. It holds something like $700 billion of government Treasuries on its books that pay interest of around 4 percent, or $28 billion of income. In any normal corporation, those profits would be distributed to the shareholders. But for the Federal Reserve, profits are freely contributed back to the Treasury of the U.S. government! In essence, they turn in their profits to contribute to keeping the federal deficit a little lower. The chairman and governors are appointed by the president and approved by Congress, so it’s pretty clear that the Fed is in bed with the federal government.
It’s also pretty clear that the Federal Reserve, on a day-to-day basis, does everything it can to support, bail out, and only loosely regulate its shareholders—namely, the big banks. The origins of the Federal Reserve, which was concocted by big bankers in a secret meeting on Jekyll Island off the coast of Georgia, indicate its founding mission of supporting the bankers.
It is my conclusion that the Federal Reserve acts as a handmaiden for the banks and also the policy tool for the federal government. The role of leadership requires balancing the conflicting goals of its different constituents. Notice who is not represented: the general public!
The Federal Reserve’s responsibilities are officially assigned two somewhat conflicting objectives:
1. To support the dollars that it issues, in such a way that they maintain their value
2. To support the growth of the overall economy
The conflict arises between the obvious balancing act of supporting the dollar by keeping interest rates high and, on the reverse side, supporting the economy by keeping interest rates low, thereby making loans easier to obtain. The problem, of course, with low interest rates and expanding debt is that the combination can lead to inflation, which decreases the purchasing power of the dollar. So the two goals are in conflict. The Fed has to navigate to what it believes is a happy medium.

How Is the Fed Affecting Our Investment Horizon?

All these structural mechanics are merely outlines of what the Federal Reserve has been defined to be. The real crux of the matter for investment analysis is for us to interpret what the Fed policymakers are doing and how big an impact this can have on the economy.
This provides opportunities for investment from interpreting what will be the future financial outcome, most importantly for the interest rates and the value of the dollar.
The first and most obvious of the extreme actions the Federal Reserve took to respond to the Credit Crisis of 2007-2008 was to cut the overnight interest rate to almost 0 percent. That means that banks can borrow at practically no cost. When they make loans, the profits that come from the spread between their borrowing and their lending cost can now be quite large. By this measure, it’s a wonderful time to be a bank.
On the other hand, all the existing banks now sit with the problem that many of their loans made in previous and more optimistic times are now falling into delinquency and some fraction will disappear in default, costing the banks hundreds of billions. That is why there are such huge bailouts to keep these institutions alive.
It would seem to me that just putting these institutions out of business and starting new banks would have given us a much cleaner result, with much less cost to the taxpayers. Our policymakers (especially Hank Paulson, who had been chairman of investment bank Goldman Sachs, and Ben Bernanke) made the policy decision to use government money (your tax dollars) to bail out overleveraged and deceptive financial institutions. Their argument was that these banks were somehow necessary for the rest of the economy and thus were too big to allow to fail. The bailout programs have reached unimaginable proportions, now counted in the trillions of dollars. The new Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner is following in the same footsteps.

The Fed Is Out of Control

In the hundred-year history of the Fed, there has never been anything even close to the kind of egregious expansion of the Federal Reserve balance sheet we are currently seeing. A major policy action of the Federal Reserve has been to debase its existing balance sheet. Prior to 2007, the Federal Reserve balance sheet contained nearly riskless federal government debt issues of the Treasury in the form of Treasury bonds, Treasury bills, and Treasury notes.
Figure 4.1 shows the incredible growth of toxic waste that has been piled into the assets of the Federal Reserve, doubling its entire balance sheet in the process.
As you can see, in the first year of this crisis, the Federal Reserve bought up many strange forms of cats and dogs, and they paid for the mangy creatures by selling off their much more stable T-bills, T-bonds, and T-notes. Put simply, in the first round of this crisis (in 2007), the Fed sold off the family jewels to fund the early bailouts, rather than printing up money, thereby keeping inflation in check.
Figure 4.1 Federal Reserve Credit Easing Policies
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
063
But by the second round (in 2008)—where the total of the graph in Figure 4.1 spikes much higher, from $1 trillion to $2 trillion—the Federal Reserve threw all caution to the wind and began printing money in earnest. Nothing like this has ever been done before in the entire history of the Federal Reserve. The Fed did it with many different kinds of newly invented programs:
• The Fed bought toxic-waste assets from the banks.
• It accepted as collateral toxic waste against loans to the banks.
• It intervened in specific markets, such as the commercial paper and money market funds.
The Fed has certainly benefited participants in the specific markets where it has poured money into the system. But it has done this at great risk to the dollar, because it has created money that will flow through the banking system in an inflationary way when the economy recovers.
To evaluate the effects of the various programs, I have combined them into categories. Figure 4.1 shows the five steps the Federal Reserve took; here’s what each step illustrates:
1. The Fed delayed major introduction of programs as it worked out how serious the situation had become and what its legal authorities were. The first step was to provide significant direct funding to particular financial institutions, and to fund that by selling off its holdings of government Treasuries. The total money supply was not changed, so inflationary forces were modest.
2. By the second half of 2008, after the collapse of Lehman Brothers in August, the Federal Reserve became aggressive in bailing out financial institutions. The big jump in the assets occurred at this time.
3. At the same time, new liquidity was provided to specific markets that had pretty much shut down, as lenders became fearful of getting their money back. Normally, such a big increase in money would be inflationary, but banks have not been making new loans, so the effects are small so far.
4. As panic receded, the Federal Reserve was able to pull back much of its lending to financial institutions, and it used those proceeds to develop two new programs to purchase mortgage-backed securities and Federal Agency debt, with the clear objective of supporting the housing market and indirectly the banking institutions involved in mortgage operations. Interest rates for mortgages have come down. The purchases are huge, with a promised program of $1.25 trillion for mortgage-backed securities (MBSs) and $200 billion for Agency debt.
5. The Federal Reserve also embarked on a program to buy $300 billion of federal government Treasuries. From one view, this is simply restoring some of the previously sold-off Treasuries on the Fed’s balance sheet. From another view, it’s dangerous for the Federal Reserve to buy up federal government debt because it is this very process that nets out to printing money for the federal government to spend through its deficits, and it is a signal for eventual inflation.
So the Federal Reserve came to the rescue somewhat belatedly but with programs that can potentially be damaging to the dollar. The problem is that the Federal Reserve now has all kinds of questionable assets on its books that could be very difficult to sell if it were to try to exit its big easing programs. The Federal Reserve has been secretive, defying lawsuits and opposing even basic government auditing. It won’t explain the details of who obtained what support and the actual value of the assets on its books. Foreigners are asking questions, and the most likely interpretation is that if the Federal Reserve can act so precipitously, then the long-term purchasing power of the dollar is very much in question. This kind of monetary expansion has almost always led to significant price inflation in the following periods.

How Did the Fed Pay for Its Big Expansion?

Of course, as on every balance sheet, liabilities must match assets. In the case of the Fed, it’s important to understand the changes in the nature of its liabilities as they spiked higher along with assets. How that was accomplished can help us understand much about the economic environment we are now in, so let’s take a look at Figure 4.2.
Historically, the Federal Reserve’s main purpose was to issue paper dollar currency. That’s what the bottom chunk in Figure 4.2 identifies. As you can see, currency has grown only modestly in the whole time of this graph of 2007-2009. The only important liability that the Fed had on its balance sheet until mid-2008 was the currency. All that changed as the credit crisis became a panic.
What is clearly far from normal is that the Federal Reserve has invented deposits out of thin air to buy up all those toxic assets from the banks. The Federal Reserve invents a deposit at the Federal Reserve in the name of the institution from which it buys Treasuries, MBS (or toxic assets). It then winds up with the assets, and the institution now has an account to spend as it wishes. That provides banks and other financial institutions with a lot of cash to keep on deposit at the Federal Reserve. Normally, such deposits would be drawn down and invested in other loans that would pay interest. Until 2009, no interest was paid on the deposits at the Federal Reserve. But now, with the Federal Reserve paying interest, the banks have not drawn down these excess reserves, and they are still sitting at the Federal Reserve.
Figure 4.2 Federal Reserve Liabilities Grew from Deposits
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
064
The monetary base is defined as currency in circulation plus the reserves at the Fed. The total is what the Fed is supposed to be able to control. The longer-term picture, shown in Figure 4.3, shows how unprecedented the current expansion has become.
If banks acted in a manner consistent with history, they would loan those deposits, helping to expand business and otherwise generate economic activity. But in the current unprecedented situation, the banks are not interested in taking on new risks, and many traditional customers find they are already overleveraged and don’t want to take on additional borrowing. In short, despite having plenty of deposits, banks don’t want to lend, and borrowers don’t want to borrow; so new lending has pretty much dried up. There was the big jump in deposits in mid-2008, and there is a worrisome increase just starting again at the end of 2009.
As a consequence, these huge balances owned by the banks just sit on deposit at the Federal Reserve. That’s important, because it has helped keep the inflationary pressure from the Federal Reserve’s actions in check. That would not have been the case had the banks withdrawn the deposits from the Fed to make new loans, thereby multiplying the lending and borrowing throughout the banking system.
Figure 4.3 Monetary Base Jumped Like Never Before from Bailouts
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
065
The more inclusive measures of our money supply include deposits at banks, and they have not grown in the dramatic way that the monetary base has grown. Figure 4.4 shows increases in the monetary measures, but nothing like the extreme rate of the monetary base. So at this juncture, we are not seeing the downstream effects of large inflationary pressure.
What might get the banks lending again? Logically, the appearance of tangible green shoots, but not the overhyped green dye that is being sprayed over the dead roots that abound in today’s economy. But it’s also entirely plausible that an activist administration and Congress will decide to forcefully encourage the banks to lend, either through dictate or by unleashing a new wave of loan guarantees that offer the banks all the upside, with little or no downside, if the loans go bad.
An important measure of whether the Fed’s bailouts are working is to monitor whether banks are expanding their lending. It’s important because it’s the basis of the administration’s goal to “get capital markets working again.” Figure 4.5 shows how banks are trying to reinflate the bubble, but it’s not working; the banks are still not making new loans.
Figure 4.4 Money Is Growing, but Not Like the Monetary Base
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
066
Figure 4.5 Banks Cut Back Loans, Despite Fed Easing
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
067
My conclusion is that we are not out of the woods. I do not agree with Ben Bernanke’s assessment that things may be getting better.

Money Creation at the Fed: Is There Any More to It Than Dropping Money from Helicopters?

Money creation at the Fed is central to understanding the likelihood of inflation going forward. Figure 4.6 shows three progressively more complex descriptions of how the important players and the systems work.
The top of Figure 4.6 shows the simplest view: If the Fed prints up more money, which then chases the same quantity of goods, then the prices of the goods will rise, creating inflation. This is the simple description that has been attributed to Bernanke for getting the economy going and making sure prices don’t fall. Bernanke is famous for repeating Milton Friedman’s suggestion that the Fed could drop money from helicopters to ensure that there was enough money so that prices wouldn’t fall. The first line in Figure 4.6 describes that process in an overly simple fashion.
Figure 4.6 Three Models of Federal Reserve Money Creation
068
But it is really much more complicated than just having the Fed print up some dollars. Whether we have money in a checking account or paper dollars in our hand, we think of both of them as money. The decision to have paper dollars is a convenience for consumers and businesses. If a lot of people want to have extra dollars in their pocket around Christmas, they can go to their banks and exchange their check for paper dollars. The Federal Reserve makes sure that the banks can drive up their Brink’s truck to exchange their demand deposits that were just described for paper dollars.
The official name for our paper dollars is Federal Reserve Notes. Exchanging paper for checking account money doesn’t affect the consumer’s ability to spend, so the measure of money supply that is most commonly used is the sum of paper money and demand deposits at banks. That is often called “narrow money supply,” and the Fed reports it every week with the name “M1.”
The creation of demand deposits, however, is extremely important because there are more of them than paper dollars. The simplest way to create them is for a person to deposit Federal Reserve Notes into their checking account.

How the Fed Really Creates Money

The root way new money is created by the Fed is for the Fed to purchase an asset from the open market, like from a bank, of something like a group of Treasury bonds. To do so, it creates out of thin air a deposit at the Federal Reserve, which is in the name of the bank for the price of the Treasuries it purchased. It is this creation of the deposit out of thin air that is called “printing money.” Notice that there was no paper dollars involved at this stage. To complete the cycle, a bank could draw down its deposit at the Fed, just as you or I would write a check to pay a bill. The commercial banks’ deposits at the Fed are called reserve deposits.

Banks Create More Money than the Federal Reserve

But now the fun of our system gets more complex. It is the banks that create much more deposits than the Federal Reserve makes of paper money plus reserve deposits at the Fed. This happens by the magic of the money multiplier, where the new money “printed” by the Fed is multiplied through the commercial banks into many times the original deposit.
That happens by the commercial bank loaning out the money it gets, say from selling a Treasury bond to the Fed. The complex part of the system is that the borrower typically buys something (for example, a house) from a person who now deposits that money into another bank. That other bank then has new money to make a new loan. This process could theoretically go on forever, but the structure of the U.S. money and banking system is that the Federal Reserve requires all banks to keep a fraction of deposits called the “reserve requirement” on the books of the Federal Reserve. That requirement is nominally 10 percent, but as we shall see, it is actually much less in practice.
With the first bank only able to loan out 90 percent of the new deposit, the second bank can only lend out 90 percent of the 90 percent of its new deposit, and the process eventually converges on a maximum creation of new deposits that is 10 times the original new deposit. Thus, in the example just described, the banks create 10 times as much money as the Fed does. It is through this process of lending and relending slightly smaller amounts multiple times that the banks are responsible for the majority of new credit (i.e., money) created, not the Fed. The Fed simply starts the process with its high-powered money. The details are elaborate, but the big-picture view is that it is easy to create credit, which acts as money.
A multiplication of the money is included in the second model of the money creation system, shown in the middle of Figure 4.6.

There’s More Money Created by Non-Banks

New loan funds come from not just our banks, but also from insurance companies, government-sponsored enterprises (GSE), money market funds, and many other institutions that create credit. So a key part of understanding the supply of credit is recognizing that the availability of funds (from all the different parts of our financial sector) goes beyond just the banks. Asset-backed securities (ABS) are suppliers of credit, as are Ginnie Mae and Fannie Mae loans, which have much the same function as bank loans. Traditional economics books describe only the banking system, and the money measures (which are published as M1, M2, M3) are measures of the deposits (on the liabilities side of the balance sheet) of only bank ledgers, so they ignore the credit creation of these other institutions.
Any GSE- or ABS-issuing entity can participate in facilitating credit, where they take in money to be loaned out. They are sometimes called “non-bank banks,” because they are not regulated like banks, but they borrow and lend like banks except they don’t take deposits. Thus, the amount of credit that can be created is larger than what is measured by the deposits of traditional banks and is reported by the Fed as M1 and M2. These non-bank institutions have no reserve requirement and have no Federal Deposit Insurance.
As an example of a newer kind of money, Figure 4.7 shows how rapidly money market funds have grown. They were invented in the 1970s as a way to provide higher interest rates than the regular banking system was allowed to pay on checking accounts. Now, our brokers offer them to us so easily that we don’t think about what category of money they represent. Figure 4.7 shows that institutional money funds and retail money funds added together are $3.5 trillion. The traditional narrow measure of money, M1, which is a combination of currency, normal demand deposits (checking accounts) and a few smaller items like traveler’s checks, is only half as much at $1.7 trillion.
Figure 4.7 Money Market Funds are Bigger than M1
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
069
I think the less-well-informed also skip over the complexity of our physical paper money. How much paper money in our pockets gets printed is just the decision of all of us as to whether we want cash in dollar bills or in our checking account. The physical printing to meet that preference is different from the Fed and commercial banks inventing deposits out of thin air. M1 adds together demand deposits of $440 billion and paper Federal Reserve Notes of $859 billion, and a few cats and dogs like travelers checks, for a total of $1,655 billion. The effect on the system’s ability to expand through multiplying deposits is different for paper cash, as it can’t be loaned and reloaned.
The next complexity is that there are plenty of sources of immediately available transactions accounts that are not formal checking accounts. One way that developed was the ability of banks to “sweep” demand deposits into savings accounts overnight. Because the reserve requirement on savings accounts is zero, the banks were able to avoid leaving cash on deposit at the Fed earning no interest. These made the measure M1 understate the amount of money available for transactions. The newer measure, called Money of Zero Maturity (MZM), at $9,550 billion, attempts to count up the funds that can immediately be used to buy things (as opposed to savings accounts, which have a term). MZM is much bigger than M1. (And bigger than M2.) It is calculated by starting with the M2, adding institutional money funds, and subtracting small denominated-time deposits. It gets more complicated as you peel back the covers of the definitions of money because there is no good definition that is clear.
And that problem is based on the fact that there is no redeemable value for any of the measures for money, except the confidence that others will trade real things for the money. At root, the whole scheme is a CONfidence game, or at least based on the confidence that the dollars will continue to buy things. That arose out of historical convention from when dollars were convertible to gold before 1971. Now dollars are not convertible to anything officially, but of course they are convertible to everything at whatever the conventional mass psychology of the value of money says they are worth. The Fed, as part of the government, can create money for itself and the government to spend, and the banks can loan money that they create to collect interest and make gains. The commercial banking system creates far more of the money in the form of newly invented deposits for loans than does the Fed. So there is plenty of reason for the owners of this system to keep it going. If they overuse the creation, they create bubbles and diminish the purchasing power of the money they are creating. So there is some limit on their dilution of the money pool. But since they get the first use and all the benefit, the incentives are to continue to create more money while talking of being “vigilant” and having an “exit strategy” to keep the image of money having value from being damaged at its source. I think it is all a sham, and when the majority of holders realize that the emperor hasn’t any clothes, there will be a run on the confidence in this dollar fiat system. As to when, I keep thinking it will happen in my lifetime, but really I am amazed at the asset deflation that occurred in 2009.

How Effective Is the Reserve Requirement at Controlling Money?

The theoretical restraint on the credit growth of bank lending is supposed to be the reserve requirement. Our fractional reserve banking system allows banks to lend out all but the fraction called a “reserve,” which is nominally at 10 percent of deposits. It is assumed that banks want to earn money by collecting the interest on loans, so they would always make as many loans as they have money to do so.
It is a great business. They start with a million dollars and can immediately make loans of $10 million and collect interest on all those loans. As long as they pick borrowers who pay back the loans, they quickly get rich. The Fed is supposed to watch over this reserve requirement to keep credit in line. But the Federal Reserve changes that decreased the requirement to have reserves on deposit have become so small that there really is no control on the banks. Reserve requirements used to be 40 percent, but now through various regulations the official requirement of 10 percent overstates the actual requirement. Banks are free to expand credit greatly and have done so. Figure 4.8 shows how small reserves really were up until the big bailout, at a trivial $10 billion.
Figure 4.8 Banks Meet Reserve Requirement with ATM Cash
SOURCE: Federal Reserve.
070
Since 1990, required reserves have fallen even while banking and deposits have grown. The Fed eliminated the reserve requirement on large time deposits in 1990 and lowered the requirement on transaction accounts in 1992. A more important source of the decline in required reserves came from the invention of sweep accounts. Funds in bank customers’ retail checking accounts are swept overnight into savings accounts that are exempt from reserve requirements and then put back into customers’ checking accounts the next day. This explains the relatively small size of total demand deposits and the related decline in reserve requirements.
The current credit crisis is not driven by banks’ inability to meet reserve requirements. The Federal Reserve has done its job to make sure that the requirements are not limiting their ability to make new loans. Because banks are not up against the reserve requirement limit, adding more liquidity does not multiply through the banking system in additional loans. The banks have other problems that are limiting their expansion of credit.
The problem for the banks is that their losses have wiped out their equity so that the banks are close to insolvency. They made bad loans, profits were lost, and many banks will be forced to close. It was claimed by Paulson that the big banks were so important to the country that we must use trillions of dollars to bail them out or the rest of the economy would grind to a halt. I personally don’t believe that. I think Paulson scared Congress and took the money from the taxpayers to bail out the corrupt bankers.
Bank lending is constrained by the capital adequacy requirement more than the reserve requirement. The Bank for International Settlements (BIS) sets this requirement for all the banks of the world, and countries apply the requirement as they can. The capital requirement is more complicated than the reserve requirement, but it explains why banks, which can create money, are going bankrupt. A bank’s capital is its assets minus its liabilities. Assets are “risk-weighted,” with some being considered riskier than others. The capital adequacy rule requires that the ratio of a bank’s capital to its assets with a risk-weighting of 1 be at least 8 percent. In other words, the bank must have $8 in capital for every $100 in ordinary loans. Federal bonds have a risk-weighting of zero; mortgage loans have a risk weighting of .5.
If loans have to be written down, a bank may suddenly find that its assets are insufficient to support its liabilities. That makes it insolvent and unable to make new loans.
Credit default swaps (CDSs) are sold as insurance against default. When the housing bubble burst and the insurance companies couldn’t meet their payments for default, the value of the derivatives protecting securitized mortgages became so questionable that they were unmarketable at any price. Banks counting them as assets on their books then had to mark them to effectively zero, reducing the banks’ capital below the levels called for in the Basel Accords and rendering the banks officially insolvent.
Some numbers from the Z1 report will help explain how big the financial institution’s supply of credit is. The financial sector in 2000 was borrowing $8,158 billion, and in 2008 it was $17,080 billion, which is an increase of 209 percent. GDP grew only 145 percent (from $9,952 billion to $14,441 billion).
So the reason interest rates are low is that there is a huge supply of credit from our financial institutions. That should be no surprise, considering the policy that brought us to the .25 percent overnight rate.
The problem is that this credit creation provides the money to bid up prices not just of Treasuries, but of all kinds of assets. Soaring asset prices, first in stocks in the 1990s and in houses to 2006, are the result of not only the relaxed policies of the Fed, but the expansive policies of the banks in creating lots of money (i.e., credit), which caused prices to rise and the purchasing power of our currency to decrease commensurately.

So Why Are We Seeing Deflation in Stocks and Houses Now?

In a fiat money system, with no required gold backing, there is little limit to how much money can be created. But what is not recognized by the simple paradigm is that for large amounts of money to be created, the banks have to be creating the money along with the Fed.
Deflation could occur if the Federal Reserve were to adopt a policy of raising reserve requirements and selling off assets like Treasuries to absorb money that it previously created. That is the exact opposite of what the Fed is doing now. For deflation to occur, there would have to be a contraction of credit, and that can also occur from the banking sector itself in spite of the action of the Fed. That is what we experienced in 2009: The banks were not lending.
The key problem for the Fed in 2009 was the unusual situation that the restrictions and reasons for not making loans held the banks back from the traditional process of making loans that would create a multiple of new money for the system. Quite simply, the Fed gave banks hundreds of billions of new reserve deposits, but the banks sat on their hands not making loans.
That is the situation in the lower third part of Figure 4.6 of my models of the banking system. It is like the old story of leading a horse to water but not being able to make him drink. Banks normally want to expand loans, because they make money from the interest on the loans. But in 2009, there were fewer qualified buyers at the higher standards required of borrowers, and the banks were having the problem of not enough ready cash to cover problem loans. Also the Fed now pays .25% on deposits.
They perhaps justifiably are not making loans. The result is that the massive stimulus of the Fed has gone only to bail out the bad loans and hasn’t stimulated the economy with new loans for new spending. So we experienced deflation of asset prices in the first half of 2009 in the housing market and the stock market—even in the face of the most expansive set of stimuluses ever taken by the Fed. In essence, the Fed printing-press theory isn’t working, yet.

Foreigners Are Partners in Our Credit Supply

This requirement for banks to lend to grow the economy is generally understood by bankers and economists. But there is another important complexity to this model that must be covered to think about what may be the next steps in this unwinding world economic crisis. It is the relationship of foreigners to the U.S. trade deficit and their flow of money. Chapter 2, on the trade deficit, explains in more detail how foreigners reinvest their trade dollars back into the United States. In fact, they have been so generous that they bought all the new debt of the U.S. government for the decade up to 2006.
When the federal government spends more than it taxes, it is adding dollars to the private sector for business and households to spend. It is stimulative. If foreigners provide the money to buy the Treasuries, the U.S. private sector does not have to spend money buying Treasuries and the federal government could fund its deficit.
But there is a very big problem looming. The budget deficit in 2009 exploded to four times what it was in the last record year of 2008. It went from $455 billion to $1.4 trillion. The trade deficit declined to a little over $400 billion.
Foreigners may find better things to do with their dollars than buy U.S. Treasuries. They could buy U.S. mining interests. That would cause two problems: The prices of mining interests might rise as the demand rose, and the Treasury would now have to find other sources from whom to borrow the money to fund the huge deficits. Consumers have plenty of credit-card obligations to pay down, so they are not likely to expand big loans to the government. Banks now have some funds for buying Treasuries from their excess reserves, but not at the level required to cover the massive budget deficit.
Thus, the likely response is for the Federal Reserve to make new dollars available with which to buy the new Treasuries. Even though the Fed will still buy them in the open market, the net effect is the same as if they bought them directly from the Treasury.
The reason this last model is important to watch is that the significance of the foreign investment in keeping the dollar strong and rates low is not emphasized enough and not understood well enough. The process kept inflation low in the United States for the last two decades, even as the U.S. banking system went on a leverage loan spree that would otherwise have been very inflationary.
Cheap foreign manufactured goods kept prices low, and the recycling of the trade surplus by foreigners into our credit market kept the dollar strong and interest rates low. Normally, the large amount of debt creation in the United States would have forced the dollar down and rates higher and would have led to higher inflation.
The important point is that protection by foreigners is about to be unmasked. If foreigners were to sell off their holdings, it would be even worse. If they just stopped buying government debt, it would leave the Treasury with no other source of funding than the Fed printing. We can see that the long-term implications lead toward dollar weakness and inflation. The big issue is that the budget deficits can be met only by Federal Reserve printing of money. The Fed will be creating deposits out of thin air to buy Treasuries, and the government will be using those deposits to fund its programs. Foreigners have already stated their desire to diversify out of the dollar, which means that they cannot be expected to be buying as much of our financial paper.

The Government Is Supporting the Economy Rather Than the Dollar

It is generally understood that as a government expands its deficit, it does so eventually through the process of creating more of its own money to fill the gap between taxes and spending. (Here, I am including the Fed as part of the government.) That additional money chasing goods drives the price of goods up and the value of the currency down. The United States has avoided much of that inflationary pressure by the kindness of foreigners as we have bought their cheaply manufactured goods and they have dutifully reinvested their trade surpluses in our government debt. As the world’s reserve currency, the U.S. dollar has avoided the typical inflationary pressures that these twin deficits would bring to the currency of other nations.
Because virtually no currency in the world has any connection to a specific anchor of value, all currencies derive their value from the confidence of the people using them. The game is that holders will be able to pass the currency (or bank check) on to the next party at somewhere near its present value.
Confidence is absolutely crucial to maintaining this house of cards of our world currency system. A fiat currency is more fragile than the banking system. One reason this fragile system works is that all the governments and central banks have a vested interest in maintaining the status quo. After all, they benefit greatly by printing their own money.
By understanding that our governments want to kick the can down the road, we see how deeply out of balance the system has become. The most obvious conclusion one can make about the many public pronouncements by Bernanke, Geithner, Summers, and Obama is that they want to maintain and grow our economy even at the cost of eventual dollar debasement.
I have been talking for years about the dilemma of a rock and a hard place, where if the Federal Reserve defends the dollar by raising interest rates, it faces a declining economy, or if it does the reverse of flooding the market and world with liquidity in which it hopes to expand the economy, it will cause the dollar to decline. We now know the direction our leaders have taken: They are fanning the flames of dollar demise with the hopes that the short-term economic situation can be patched up by adding more liquidity to specific problem areas. Although international markets have not reacted yet, I think we are close to the point of no return because of the size of these huge deficits, bailouts, and interventions.

Federal Reserve’s New Inflation Policy

The Federal Reserve embarked on a new policy in the spring of 2009 of bailing out mortgage-backed securities by committing to buy $1.25 trillion worth. It is also buying $200 billion of agency debt and $300 billion of Treasuries. The shift is dramatic, as presented in Figure 4.9. The goal is to keep interest rates low and to stimulate and support mortgage lending. This quantitative easing has added a tremendous amount of liquidity. Because the other direct lending to troubled banks and other market support has been declining, the Fed’s balance sheet has been steady.
The process is entirely different from how the Fed approached its early bailouts at the end of 2007, where it directly provided funds by selling off $200 billion of its short-term T-bills. So, in essence, it gave the market funds with one hand, as it drained it with the other. The net created only moderate new money for the system.
Looking to the future, there seems to be no way for the federal government to borrow $1.5 trillion in 2010 without great assistance from the Federal Reserve. Although the Federal Reserve has announced that it would purchase $300 billion of longer-term Treasuries, the government borrowing suggests that the Fed may purchase up to $1 trillion of Treasuries to fund the federal deficit at the ongoing rate. This amount of expansion of the Federal Reserve balance sheet could damage the dollar. Tim Geithner was laughed at in China when he said that Chinese investment in U.S. securities was safe. This kind of Fed expansion will not be ignored, and the direction is toward inflation.
Figure 4.9 The Fed Switched from Noninflationary Actions to an Inflationary Policy in Mid-2008
071

Who Will Buy All the Treasuries?

The huge jump in the federal government’s projected budget deficit raises the question of who will buy all the debt that will have to be issued to fund spending.
Trying to identify who will ultimately step up to buy up the next wave of government debt, I look past the current holdings and focus on the recent buying patterns of the four sectors. It will, after all, have to be buying by some combination of these sectors that, in total, cover the government’s deficit. So, which of the sectors have been buying more recently?
As you can see in Figure 4.10, I expect a big jump in Treasury purchases by both the private domestic holders and by foreigners. This increased buying reflects the move by investors, concerned about defaults in mortgage-backed and other securities, into the “safe harbor” of government-issued paper.
In an attempt to look forward, I’ve spent a considerable amount of time developing defensible projections, which are also reflected in Figure 4.10. These projections indicate that while both foreigners and domestic investors will continue to buy Treasuries, they’ll do so at a lower level. Let’s look at each group:
Foreigners: In the case of foreigners, the trade surplus is their source of ready cash. That is in steep decline, from about $750 billion annually down to about $500 billion now. They have fewer funds available to invest, and usually follow that source.
Private Domestic Holders are made up of two groups: households and businesses. Households’ net worth is decimated by the economic
Figure 4.10 The Federal Reserve Will Have to Buy Treasuries to Fund the Deficit
072
downturn, and their incomes are hit by the recession, so they simply don’t have the economic firepower to make new investments. There could be purchases of Treasuries by the financial sector, as they are far less willing to take on risk of new loans.
• The Trust Funds will continue purchases, although at slightly lower levels now that baby boomers born after 1945 are turning 65 years old. Thus, the surplus generated by these trust funds will not be as big a piggy bank for the Treasury to pillage.
In short, these sectors will not be able to absorb the $2 trillion deficit. And that leaves only the Federal Reserve to step up and buy the excess new issues of Treasuries.
Figure 4.10 also shows that in order to cover the government deficits of close to $2 trillion, the Federal Reserve will have to buy up to $1 trillion of Treasuries a year, according to my estimates. The mechanics of how this will be achieved may be more complex than directly buying Treasuries at Treasury auctions because that raises flags to the financial community about the demise of the independence of the Fed and the destruction of the dollar. It will involve the Fed buying Treasuries from the open market in what are called Permanent Open Market Operations (POMO).
The federal government is likely to put those newly created dollars into circulation more rapidly than when the Fed gives money to the banks. The Treasury spends the money immediately on Social Security or bombers. So this government spending will be an increasingly more effective stimulant than the bank bailouts. That is because the banks have been reluctant to make new loans with their bailouts, preferring to leave money on deposit at the Fed as I discussed earlier. The point is that deficits that are monetized are more inflationary than Fed loans to banks that hoard the money.
Many economists and bond dealers are operating under the “Pushing on a String” model, predicting deflationary results like those that occurred in the Depression. In those days the tie to gold kept the Fed from pursuing the kind of money creation that they have already done. For comparison, Roosevelt’s New Deal spending was not nearly as big as the current bailouts, not by a big margin even after correcting for the difference in purchasing power of the dollar.
Who will buy all the debt being issued to fund the government’s massive spending? The government itself (the Fed), through an equally massive amount of money creation. That will be inflationary.

When Might Deflation Turn to Inflation?

The race between asset price depreciation and the effects of the government aggressive bailout is the most important driver of whether we will have inflation or deflation. The erosion in housing and stock prices has affected the apparent wealth of everyone. Against the erosion is a wall of money emanating from the federal government and the Fed in their attempt to reinflate the collapsing bubble.
So far, the asset-deflation side of the ledger has been bigger than the bailouts.
Although I can’t know much for certain, I do know that in a fiat monetary system, such as we now operate, the Federal Reserve has the ability to crank out virtually any amount of money it deems necessary. Although there are obvious limitations in terms of how far creditors will allow the Fed to go before severely punishing the dollar, as long as price inflation continues to appear under control, the government can be expected to continue to spend, and prodigiously so.
Table 4.1 Government Bailout Programs
Stimulus Total Program Promise To Q3 2009 Commitment/Loss
Federal Reserve Total$ 7,766$1,679
FDIC Total$ 2,039$ 358
Treasury Total$ 2,694$1,834
HUD Total$ 300$ 300
Total (Billions)$12,798$4,170
To establish the magnitude of the countervailing forces, I created Tables 4.1 and 4.2. The caveat is that the numbers are fairly loose. Even so, they are sufficient for the purposes of getting a general indication of how much more money the government needs to come up with to douse the flames of collapse.
Table 4.1 summarizes the stimulus items that have been announced so far, with the amount promised by various agencies (in the middle column) and the amount actually committed by those agencies (in the right column).
Table 4.2 summarizes, using reasonable but ultimately inaccurate estimates, just how bad the losses could get at the worst (in the middle column) and what those losses are to date (in the right column).
Table 4.2 Asset and Loan Losses from Peak
Losses Potential Losses Losses Q3 2009
Stocks−$ 6,000−$ 4,000
Houses−$ 8,000−$ 6,000
Commercial RE−$ 3,000−$ 1,500
Loan loss−$ 1,800−$ 1,000
Total Losses−$18,800−$12,500
Although the losses in assets could be as bad as $18.8 trillion, the government’s total promises to date add up to only about two-thirds that level, or $12.7 trillion. Based strictly on those two numbers, the government would have to make a similar level of commitment for the first two thirds of 2010 if it were to reinflate the bubble. That may be their track, and it may be in 2010 that we see deflationary forces overcome by inflationary.
When you look at the numbers of actual current losses, $12.5 trillion versus the government’s actual commitments today, $4.2 trillion, you could come to the conclusion that the government has almost three years to go at current levels to catch up with the losses.
My methodology in Tables 4.1 and 4.2 is completely off the wall, but it gives me a range to consider when deflation might turn to inflation, which is to say at what point might the government succeed in outspending the deflationary pressures. Of course, there are many factors involved in this equation, and so this is little more than a mental exercise. I want to share with you some sense of the data that I look at when trying to come to grips with the current state of the economy and where it’s headed next. I don’t guarantee these numbers follow rigorous definitions that formal economists expect!
In July 2009, the watchdog overseeing the government bailout said the government’s maximum exposure to financial institutions since 2007 could total nearly $23.7 trillion. The headline-grabbing amount was compiled by Neil Barofsky, the inspector general for the $700 billion Troubled Asset Relief Program. This overstates the expected actual costs because many of the programs are backed by collateral and the $23.7 trillion represents the gross, not net, exposure that the government could face. He doesn’t suggest that the full amounts would be used, but the amounts do get close to the kind of unlimited spending that the government sometimes seems to be moving toward. One of his valid criticisms is that the government is not telling us precisely what organizations are getting what money, which is a red flag to me because where there is secrecy there could be fraud.
As I look more closely at the rising stock market, up 65 percent since March 2009, housing prices rising a little and crude oil doubling from depressed levels at the end of 2008, I conclude that the deflationary pressures are ready to give way to inflationary pressure in 2010 and grow thereafter.

Political Implications of Egregious Fed Spending

The Federal Reserve has moved way beyond the authority of its original charter, which was to act as a banker’s bank and to distribute our currency. It now believes it is an instrument of economic policy and is unilaterally creating credit, buying up so-called toxic waste assets, and venturing into large purchases of mortgage-backed securities and longer-term Treasuries. This is a tremendous addition to the credit markets, which will eventually lead to debasement of the dollar.
The Federal Reserve doubled its balance sheet in 2008 and could add another trillion again by the end of 2010 to meet the commitments of supporting the mortgage market and to fund the government deficit.
The complete freezing of many markets and the recognition of big financial institutions that they did not have enough capital to keep operating brought a massive response from the government. The Treasury took over Fannie and Freddie and entered the credit markets to lower rates by guarantees and new investments. To fund these bailouts, the Treasury issued massive amounts of new Treasuries. The Treasury borrowed a trillion dollars in three months. I use the word panic to describe how fast the new borrowing was accomplished. There has never been this big a jump in history except during the World Wars.
The hidden political shift in power is to concentrate wealth in the big lenders, including the banks and wealthiest people. This becomes more obvious when contrasted with the way our system is supposed to work. The big financial institutions that were overpaying their managers and traders to take unreasonable risk for short-term profits that bring personal bonuses and stock option payouts should be wiped out, including those invested in these sham institutions. Bankruptcies and investment losses would make any future institutions far more balanced with a long-term view of risk about their investment choices. We are seeing the end of capitalism and the rise of a concentrated government authority over our financial system.
After all of this it is impossible to say why money has any value at all. Before 1971, when dollars could be converted into gold at $35 an ounce by foreign central banks, there was an anchor for the dollar. Since then, dollars are merely traded on the convention of what they were worth yesterday. It is my view that the only value of dollars is from the combined opinion of all the users to agree on their value. This illusion is the greatest CONfidence game ever developed in the financial community!
It is my belief that we are on the cusp of recognizing the failures of this highly leveraged debt-based monetary system. The whole world has been caught in the economic slowing and loss of confidence in credit as this system begins to unwind.
Banks expect to take back more money in interest along with the principal that they put into the system. That is not possible on a longterm basis if money maintains it value. It would mean that bankers eventually own the world. The whole world has been captured in the debt trap of an overleveraged, too-big-to-fail banking mania and collapse.
In a fiat money system, the Quantity Theory of Money is unable to explain all that is going on. When dollars had intrinsic ties to gold, ratios of money supply to quantities of goods were sensible interpretations. But when money is whatever people think it should be worth, the mechanism of supply of money for predicting prices is no longer adequate. Prices don’t calmly decline because of a contraction in the money supply. Workers are fired, businesses cut back, and the economy goes into recession. It’s too optimistic to assume that the Fed can fine-tune prices by controlling the money supply. It is very difficult to control the money supply as there are independent players acting to create money. For example, the Fed now is increasing the part of the money supply it controls (monetary base), but we are not seeing inflation because banks are not lending. Banks make loans, and foreigners can purchase assets, both of which affect the domestic money measures. Adding Federal Reserve deposits to the system might not raise prices if foreign goods can be purchased cheaply.
It was the commercial banks, by their own money multiplying under the lax review of the regulators, that created this mess as much as it was the central bank. Commercial banks just create money as accounting entries on their books, as does the Fed. The crisis came when overextended housing loans collapsed, not because of a Fed policy change.
The bank bailout has proven to be no more than a handout to well-connected big Wall Street banks, and it didn’t get credit flowing again.
In early 2008, outstanding derivatives on the books of U.S. banks exceeded $180 trillion. However, $90 trillion of this was carried on the books of JP Morgan Chase alone, while Citibank and Bank of America each had $38 trillion on their books. Not so surprisingly, these big banks that hold incalculable amounts of derivatives on their books, are the ones that got the majority of the Treasury’s bailout money under the Troubled Asset Relief Program. Rather than getting rid of the derivatives, the trillions in taxpayer money is being used, not to unfreeze credit by making loans, but to buy up smaller banks. That means the derivative time bomb continues to tick away.

The Fed May Be Acting Beyond Its Intended Authority

It seems to me that the Fed is acting outside of the constitutional authority that gives Congress the right to allocate funds. The Federal Reserve hides behind Section 13.3 of the Federal Reserve Act talking about unusual circumstances to justify their actions. Even more egregious is that they refuse to tell us to whom they have given these special deals and buyouts, or to reveal the actual holdings of the garbage they have purchased.
Congressman Ron Paul from Texas introduced a bill into the House asking only that the Federal Reserve be subject to normal auditing scrutiny. While he has support in the Congress, and has obtained kudos from the public for his tenacity in taking on the crusade for what should be normal practice in any government operation, I am sure that the powerful banking interests will squash this bill in the Senate. We the people will be left with what we have been left since this crisis started: the responsibility for paying the bill without understanding who is getting the payoff.
The Federal Reserve Act provides for the Federal Reserve to purchase only government guaranteed securities. So it seems outside the Fed charter to be purchasing $1.25 trillion of Mortgage-Backed Securities. The Federal Reserve is trying to drive down the cost of mortgage rates to support the housing market with this huge sum. The risk to the Federal Reserve is that many of these loans might not be paid off and many homes are in foreclosure. These securities were mostly guaranteed by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Fannie and Freddie have now been taken over by the Treasury in what is called a conservatorship. The legislation allowing the Treasury takeover was rammed through Congress by Henry Paulson who said he needed the authority but claimed he doubted he would use it. Almost immediately he took over Fannie and Freddie. The legislation includes a limit of $300 billion in total, and $200 billion for each institution. But on Christmas Eve 2009, Timothy Geithner slipped out the announcement that the Treasury had unilaterally eliminated the $200 billion per institution. The result of this open-ended support for Fannie and Freddie will be that the treasury (that’s you and me) will be printing up new Treasuries to cover the losses at Fannie and Freddie, which will be induced from the $ trillion + Mortgage-Backed Securities being held by the Fed. This means that the toxic waste assets purchased by the Federal Reserve will be bailed out by the taxpayer. All this is happening without taxpayer approval.
While the actual hundreds of billions of dollars involved are enough to make us cringe, I think the roughshod trampling of the Constitution is worse. Look beyond the huge dollars involved to the precedent where now bureaucrats at the Federal Reserve, and at the Treasury, are making policy decisions and allocating money without specific congressional legal authority. It’s not that I believe Congress is a paragon of virtue in deciding financial matters, but at least they are a large deliberative body, whose decisions are made in public. The Federal Reserve, in deciding to purchase over $1 trillion of securities, did so with no specific authority except the assertion of the Chairman that there was an emergency and he thought it was the right thing to do. Personally, I consider this a usurpation of power, a dangerous precedent that was not delegated under the Constitution.
So the related problem of confidence in the dollar becomes more problematic as we see capricious actions taken to bailout specific industries with only the smallest oversight by Congress. I think this is a formula for weakening the dollar even as the domestic economy repairs itself.
Regardless of the legality, the court of international opinion will decide whether the world wants to own so many dollars, with the “vote” expressed in the strength of the U.S. dollar on foreign exchange markets and for tangibles such as gold and oil. It seems pretty clear to me that foreigners are already nervous, as seen in world leaders’ pronouncements and actions in the news.

Conclusion

The steps being taken by the Federal Reserve are both predictable and catastrophic. Bernanke told us in speeches and papers that he was positioned to make sure that the United States had all the money it needed to avoid a deflationary collapse similar to that of 1929. On the one hand, Dr. Bernanke was given a difficult set of circumstances to manage. But on the other hand, the actions he has taken to double the balance sheet, to provide liquidity to specific markets like mortgage-backed securities and commercial paper, and to provide the resources for bailouts of specific institutions are all way beyond anything that has been done before. They will eventually be paid for by taxpayers and by people losing purchasing power through inflation. Many people are incensed that rich bankers have been the first to slop at the trough of government and the Federal Reserve for special privileges and bailouts. What is smarter is to think about how these actions will affect our future and to get out of the way of the train wreck of dollar debasement.
The basic problem of the Federal Reserve is that there is virtually no restraint against it using its very powerful ability to create money. People used to say that money doesn’t grow on trees. But if you think about it for a moment, money is just a few bits in the computer. Bernanke has already abused his situation, and the only countervailing force defined by the Constitution would be actions taken by the House of Representatives to take back the management of our currency and banking system.
In fact, the opposite is being played out in the halls of Congress, by providing more powers to the Fed to mess things up even more than they already have. The Federal Reserve is the banker’s bank. It allowed the egregious expansion of credit to get out of hand, and it is now being entrusted with even more responsibility to manage in the future. The Fed does whatever it takes to manage and support the large banks that it is supposed to be regulating. We no longer have an experiment, we have results: Our banks would have failed without the support of egregious government and federal largess.
Going forward, we already understand the policy decisions that have been made to bail out our big banks and to try to stimulate economic activity, while letting the dollar be damned. Watching this system unravel will be painful. Keeping track of the various factors of our credit markets that both add liquidity and demand money for normal economic activity is at the guts of unraveling the conundrum of who the winners and losers will be. The next chapter in this section on the theoretical underpinning of how the financial markets are structured digs into the relationship between debt, money, and the economy to see how serious the current upheaval is.