We know better than to repeal our masculine systems.
—John Adams
The Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome we have described, so ubiquitous throughout recorded human history, is alive and well today. In many nations, reliance on male-bonded kin groups for security remains the norm. Indeed, nations might be placed along a spectrum according to how important this security provision mechanism remains, or as Mark Weiner notes, clan societies “range from stateless societies known as ‘segmentary lineage systems’ to modern societies in which a weak state has difficulty containing the forces of clannism. In some circumstances, they even exist in developed, centralized states.”1 In other words, just because a nation is democratic or authoritarian, rich or poor, or located in a particular region, may not be sufficient to tell us the predominant security provision mechanism in use by its citizens.
To probe whether reliance on extended male-bonded kin groups as a security provision mechanism is linked to worse outcomes for nation-states, we first must define how we gauge this degree of reliance. This is not a straightforward task; each nation’s situation is nuanced and complex, having its own idiosyncratic history, its own mixture of subnational groups, and its own contemporary trajectory. Thus, the attempt that follows should be viewed for what it must be at this stage: a first step that cannot do justice to all of the observable complexity and particularity of the nations of the world. Even so, the theoretical framework laid out in the first two chapters of this volume tell us where to start: with the situation, status, and security of women. To gauge reliance on male-bonded kin groups as the predominant security provision mechanism, we look for evidence of the Syndrome components outlined in figure 2.4 in chapter 2.
Many countries, even in the twenty-first century, have a fairly intact Syndrome-based society, meaning that the primary mechanism of security provision in the society is the patrilineal kin network.2 Weiner explains that plenty of seemingly modern states are, in fact, “founded on informal patronage networks” and “traditional ideals of patriarchal family authority.”3 In these states, “government is hijacked for purely factional purposes and the state, conceived on the model of the patriarchal family, treats citizens not as autonomous actors but rather as troublesome dependents to be managed. Clannism is the rule of the clan’s historical echo [and] often characterizes rentier societies.”4
Reliance on male-bonded kin networks as the predominant security provision mechanism within states may be open and overt, such as in contemporary Afghanistan or South Sudan, but this reliance may be present even in countries with centralized states. For example, Weiner argues:
A form of clannism likewise pervades mainland China and other nations whose political development was influenced by Confucianism, with its ideal of a powerful state resting on a well-ordered family, and where personal connections are essential to economic exchange…Likewise, the principles of clannism influence nations that long ago ceased to be organized along tribal lines but that still afford a prominent role to lineage or ethnicity, such as Bosnia, or that hold patriarchal family authority in especially high regard, such as Egypt.5
In addition, some countries are transitioning back to this reliance on male kin networks as the primary security provision mechanism after having moved away from that reliance in earlier time periods—we see this phenomenon in the post-Soviet Caucasus, for example. Explaining this regress toward the older security provision mechanism, the United Nations Development Program (UNDP) notes about that region,
Clannism flourishes, and its negative impact on freedom and society become stronger, wherever civil or political institutions that protect rights and freedoms are weak or absent. Without institutional supports, individuals are driven to seek refuge in narrowly based loyalties that provide security and protection, thus further aggravating the phenomenon. Partisan allegiances also develop when the judiciary is ineffective or the executive authority is reluctant to implement its rulings, circumstances that make citizens unsure of their ability to realize their rights without the allegiance of the clan.6
In contrast, other societies are gradually moving away from the full Syndrome, such as we have seen in South Korea’s dismantlement of the patrilineal hoju system.7 Even in these latter societies, however, we still see some of the fundamental components present, meaning that it remains possible for the Syndrome to resurge in the future if conditions are right. For example, although Latin American countries in the contemporary era do not practice brideprice or dowry, the foundation of high levels of violence against women, even to the point of widespread femicide, combined with highly inequitable family law and property ownership, as well as greater human capital investment in sons, remains and continues to undermine national outcomes. Indeed, these factors of widespread, normalized violence against women along with inequity in family and personal status law are reservoirs for Syndrome resurgence in many countries that have moved away from the full-blown Syndrome.
Wherever we find a fuller expression of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome, we know that extended male kin groups have substantial power within society. This explains why more general indicators of gender inequality within a society are insufficient for our purposes. Indicators such as female literacy, or the representation of women in parliament, for example, do not tap into the reproduction of clan exclusivity. As another example, high female labor force participation may exist even in a society encoding most of the Syndrome. As the political scientist Lindsay Benstead notes, it should trouble us that Libya ranked so well on the UNDP’s Gender Inequality Index compared with its neighbors in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) region.8 The dimensions of that index, examining health, labor force participation, and political participation, are not tapping into the proximate mechanisms of household-level disempowerment of women. Even maternal and infant mortality rates are insufficient for our purposes, because it is entirely possible to encode the Syndrome and yet deploy the nation’s resources to significantly lower those rates, as we see in the Gulf states. The prevalence of child marriage for women, the prevalence of patrilocal marriage, and other indicators of such household-level disempowerment of women can better inform us whether the reproduction of male kin group exclusivity is taking place.
In this chapter, we first provide a global overview of the Syndrome and then explore each of its components in greater detail. In this broad chapter, we focus first on how each of these control mechanisms subverts the position of women. Then in part II of this volume, we propose and then test a theoretical framework linking the degree to which a nation encodes the Syndrome to worse nation-state-level outcomes on a variety of dimensions of national security, stability, and resilience.
An Overview of the Incidence of the Syndrome Today
1. prevalence of male willingness to use physical coercion against women, which includes both levels of violence against women, and degree of sanction/impunity for such violence, to wit—
a. overall level of violence against women;
b. societal sanction for the murder of women; and
c. whether a rapist can escape punishment by offering to marry his victim (indicating that female security is but a property right belonging to males);
2. prevalence of patrilocal marriage;
3. prevalence of cousin marriage;
4. preference for sons, including sex ratio abnormalities;
5. age of first marriage for girls in law and practice;
6. overall inequity in family law/practice favoring males;
7. prevalence of brideprice and dowry;
8. prevalence of polygyny in law and practice; and
9. property rights of women in law and practice.
We then developed a scale of how closely a society came to a complete incarnation of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome using these eleven variables. We first approached construction of this scale through an exploratory factor analysis of the eleven components of the Syndrome, and followed with the creation of a combinatorial algorithm to produce the scale. Appendix I provides a full description of each of the eleven variables used to create the Syndrome score, the results of our exploratory and confirmatory factor analyses justifying the combination of these variables into the Syndrome scale, the algorithm used to combine subcomponent score, and Cronbach’s alpha measuring reliability of the scale, as well as specifies coverage of countries and time periods. The appendix also provides the Syndrome scores for 176 countries (all those with a population of at least two hundred thousand) for the time period from 2010 to 2015. We call this overall index the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome scale. This scale ranges from 0–16, with 16 being interpreted as meaning the society fully encodes the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome as its security provision mechanism, and 0 meaning that the society is free of Syndrome practices.
With this scaling in hand, we produced a map (figure 3.1) showing the 176 countries in our analysis. Mapping sixteen colors is not realistic, so for the map’s five legend colors, the cut-points we selected as inductively sound were [0,1,2], [3,4,5], [6,7,8,9], [10,11,12], [13,14,15,16]. For a dichotomous measure (Syndrome/non-Syndrome), then we propose that 0–5 would be considered as, generally speaking, non-Syndrome societies, and 6–16 would be considered, generally speaking, Syndrome societies. Furthermore, we suggest that scores of 6–9 indicate that a society is in clear transition, with either directionality of transition possible. We will utilize this trichotomy [0,1,2,3,4,5], [6,7,8,9], [10,11,12,13,14,15,16] in subsequent chapters as we explore the dynamics of change.
FIGURE 3.1 Map of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome Scale, scaled 2017
The map clearly shows the full spectrum of degree of reliance on male-bonded kin groups in the world today. Many nations lack the components of the Syndrome almost entirely, and yet in quite a few nations, the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome remains the most dominant security provision mechanism in the society and nearly all components of the Syndrome can be found. Furthermore, even today, quite a few nations in the medium-gray or transitional portion of the map experience legacy effects from earlier, fuller instantiation of the Syndrome.
The complete range of data from 0 to 16 is evident in the scale scores, with South Sudan being the lone country scaled as instantiating the fullest version of the Syndrome in the present time period at a scale point of 16. The histogram in figure 3.2 shows that countries cluster into roughly three categories of severity when it comes to the Syndrome’s enactment: we interpret these three categories as indicating non-Syndrome, Transition, and Syndrome societies.9 In the final chapter, we discuss the dynamics of change and evaluate the case of those middle countries transitioning between the two extremes: Under what conditions do these nations move away from the fuller Syndrome? Under what conditions do these nations regress toward the fuller Syndrome? What are the policy implications of the answers to these questions?
FIGURE 3.2 Histogram of Syndrome Scale scores for 176 countries
If we use a dichotomous approach, with countries scoring 5 and under deemed as no longer encoding the Syndrome, and with countries scoring 6 and above as fundamentally rooted in the Syndrome, then 56 countries are presently scaled as non-Syndrome, and 120 are scaled as Syndrome-based countries. Syndrome-based countries thus outnumber non-Syndrome countries by more than two to one. If we look only at the high-scoring countries, for which almost the full complement of Syndrome variables is evidenced (i.e., scale points 13–16), 40 countries in our sample of 176 nations currently meet that description. The Syndrome is clearly still very much with us even in the twenty-first century.
In terms of geographic distribution, the high-scoring countries are located in a belt across sub-Saharan Africa, the Middle East, West Asia, and South Asia, extending into Indonesia. Transition countries, or countries in the middle-scoring cluster of nations, show great geographic diversity, with such nations spread across all continents except for the island continent of Australia. Non-Syndrome countries are generally found in that set that might be called the member nations of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
Construct Validity Checks
Is the Syndrome scale measuring what we hope it measures? That is, does it possess “construct validity”? To assess construct validity, we examined the correlations between our Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome scale and two scales that measure the degree to which clans and tribes dominate society. We also looked at two oft-used measures of the overall situation of women. We would hope to see strong positive correlations, as the Syndrome score gauges both clan governance as well as women’s status. The Syndrome scale, however, measures both of these concepts in different ways from these other scales. The clan scales we examine, for example, emphasize variables other than whether women are controlled in marriage and are insecure; furthermore, the two scales of women’s overall situation in society that we use for the construct validity check do not focus on women’s household-level disempowerment as the Syndrome scale, but focus instead on women’s economic, education, and political participation.
The two scales we selected for this construct validity check are a tribalism scale created by David Jacobson10 and a clan governance scale created by Weiner,11 each of which represent independent approaches.12 The purpose of each scale is to gauge the degree to which extended kin networks dominate the politics of a nation-state. The bivariate correlation (N = 155) between the Syndrome scale and Jacobson’s tribalism scale was 0.487, which was significant at the 0.001 level, and that between the Syndrome scale and Weiner’s clan governance scale (N = 160) was 0.489, which again was significant at the 0.001 level.
We selected two scales of women’s overall situation in society for this construct validity check: the Global Gender Gap Index (GGI, 2016) of the World Economic Forum, and the Gender Inequality Index (GII, 2015) of the UNDP. In the GGI, a higher score is better, whereas in the Syndrome scale, a higher score is worse. Thus, we would expect a strong negative correlation between these two scales and that is what we find: the correlation between the Syndrome scale and the GGI (N = 144) is −0.670, significant at the 0.001 level. The bivariate correlation between the Syndrome scale and the GII (N = 155) was 0.800, significant at the 0.001 level.
All of these correlations are comparatively strong, significant, and in the anticipated direction. We conclude that the Syndrome scale has construct validity as a measure that seeks to capture the degree of reliance on male-bonded kin groups within a society based on a women’s situation in marriage and on their personal status and security, which in turn is reflective of the overall levels of gender inequality within a society. Because we feel the Syndrome, reflecting the first political order, is the wellspring of both of these societal-level phenomena, in a theoretical sense, we feel justified in using the Syndrome to explain the presence of clan governance and the level of gender inequality, rather than the other way around.
Before we can discuss the consequences of the Syndrome for the outcome measures of interest concerning governance, security, stability, and resilience of the nation-state in part II of this volume, we must first set the stage to see those connections by examining how each component of the Syndrome affects the lives of those who experience it, especially the women themselves. As we come to understand those experiences, we will establish the theoretical groundwork on which to put forward a variety of propositions linking the Syndrome variables to the state-level outcomes of national security, stability, and resilience.
The Individual Components of the Syndrome Today
Jacobson rightly notes that “traditional (and especially tribal) patriarchy, the rule of men,…tends to be in the mold of vitriolic hostility to women’s rights.”13 In this section, we detail how each component of the Syndrome affects the lives of women and girls as well as the pertinent effects on men and boys. The picture is unrelievedly tragic. Jacobson may be right when he suggests that it is the treatment of women and girls that represents the deepest “global fissure” in the world today,14 deeper than ethnicity or religion or ideology. As he puts it, “This is the first global struggle over the nature of the self…A critical issue is ‘self possession,’ or who owns and controls one’s body, especially when it comes to women: is it the individual herself or the community[?] Women are now at the heart of the world’s most dangerous quarrel.”15
We argue that the tragic consequences of women’s subordination are not confined to women, but extend to all men, all children, and all nations in which the Syndrome organizes society. In this chapter, we explore the effects of the Syndrome on women and girls, and to a lesser extent men and boys, but in part II, we explore the wider national-level effects, demonstrating that the Syndrome affects virtually all aspects of the nation-state’s situation, including political, economic, and security dimensions.
What follows is an overview of each of the eleven subcomponents of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome scale, emphasizing how each means of control functions to support the male-bonded kin group, and how each undercuts the position of women and girls.
Some people who live in the Western hemisphere might be surprised to learn that the practices of brideprice and dowry are prevalent in the early twenty-first century. The societies that maintain these practices represent almost half of the world’s countries, and account for far more than half the world’s population—indeed, more accurately, almost three-quarters of the world’s population—and span a wide range of regime types, including communist one-party rule in countries such as China.17 Brideprice, or payment from a groom to the bride’s family, is far more common than dowry, or payment from the bride’s family to the groom, in today’s world. David Barash finds that two-thirds of societies in the Ethnographic Atlas practice brideprice, with only a few, largely South Asian societies practicing dowry today.18
Several patterns can be seen in figure 3.3: a regional pattern, an economic pattern, and a cultural pattern. Jack Goody noted in 1974 of the former that “the data shows the dominance of bridewealth in all continents except America.”19 In the modern day, we would include Australia, Europe, and other cultures such as Japan. As for the economic pattern, setting aside the Americas for a moment, we also see that more developed countries do not practice brideprice. As anthropologists Alice Schlegel and Rohn Eloul note, “Absence of marriage transactions, beyond the small gifts that usually accompany the establishment of social bonds everywhere, is itself of interest, as it implies that property, and the reallocation of labor or status, either are not critical issues for those households or are not negotiated through marriage.”20
FIGURE 3.3 Map of Brideprice/Dowry/Wedding Costs, scaled 2016
Finally, with regard to ethno-religious patterns, predominantly Christian cultures appear less likely to practice brideprice in the contemporary era. There are reports of Christian missionaries inveighing against the practice during the colonial period, likening it to slavery.21 The case of sub-Saharan Africa deserves special mention: although sub-Saharan Africa has a strong Christian presence, Christians account for only about 38 percent of the population, and Christian families often find it difficult to part ways with the larger culture on this practice.22 In this area, therefore, one can find substantial representation of Christians in countries where brideprice is prevalent. Although this and other regional, economic, and cultural exceptions exist, brideprice is a dominant practice in much of the world. Indeed, those living in countries without this practice may underestimate the prevalence and importance of this custom.
Our own scaling of brideprice/dowry finds a roughly equal bimodal distribution, shown in the histogram in figure 3.4, among the nations of the world. As noted earlier, however, about three-quarters of the world’s population lives in countries that still practice brideprice/dowry.23 Although there are profound consequences of brideprice/dowry for societal stability, which will be explored in the next chapter, we confine this discussion to an examination of the effects of this practice on women.
FIGURE 3.4 Histogram of Brideprice/Dowry/Wedding Costs Scale
(Note: 0 indicates no brideprice, dowry, or obligatory wedding costs)
The natural consequences that grow out of this system are deeply detrimental to the status of women, despite the fact that the practice is often justified as a protection to women in case they are divorced by their husbands. In addition to patrilocal marriage and lack of property rights, brideprice/dowry societies are characterized by arranged marriage in the patriline’s interest, relatively low age of marriage for girls, profound underinvestment in female human capital, intense son preference, highly inequitable family and personal status law favoring men, and chronically high levels of violence against women as a means to enforce the imposition of the patrilineal system on often recalcitrant women. Consider the findings of a Tanzanian women’s organization following an extensive survey that “due to brideprice,” women suffer “insults, sexual abuse, battery, denial of their rights to own property, being overworked and having to bear a large number of children.”24 One female assembly member in Ghana noted that “some of the young men who were able to afford the items [in the brideprice] treated their wives as ‘slaves’ or ‘properties’ they had acquired with their wealth because of the huge sums they spent.”25 Psychiatric researcher Susan Rees and her colleagues, studying brideprice in Timor-Leste, find strong associations to intimate partner violence (IPV) against women, women’s anger and mental distress, and a deep feeling of injustice among women whose marriages involved the payment of brideprice.26
An IRIN report relays that “Women also complained of some men’s tendency to reclaim the brideprice when marriages broke up, saying fear of this outcome forced women to cling to their marriages even when abused.”27 An article from a Ghanaian newspaper concurs: “Women who wanted to divorce their husbands because of ill treatment were made to return the exact dowry collected before the marriage, and since most families are not able to refund the items, the women are left to suffer in the marriage.”28
Journalist Marc Ellison tells the story of Grace in rural Tanzania, who refused to marry an older man, and then was abducted at age twelve and forcibly married to him so that her father could obtain the negotiated brideprice. The human toll for these girls is catastrophic: Grace was beaten and raped every day for eleven months until her husband died in a motor accident, leaving her penniless and with a baby. In Grace’s case, the brideprice was in cows, and she comments, “Bitterness still fills my heart when I look at them [the cows]; Given what I went through, I wish I had been born a cow. That day felt like the end of everything.”29 Ellison notes that in Grace’s region of Tanzania, almost 60 percent of girls are married as children, and it gives pain to note that the motto of the men in her ethnic group is “alcohol, meat, and vagina,” naming the three things to which every man is entitled. Of course, that “vagina” is attached to a real, living human being.
As noted in chapter 2, two variants of the Syndrome also demand our attention, particularly given their effects on the status of women overall. First, where women’s work is valued in the productive labor of the society, such as farm labor, brideprice and polygyny are often prevalent. Given that marriage is patrilocal and inheritance effected through the patriline, buying or exchanging women between descent groups becomes essential, and brideprice becomes the reimbursement to the family who invested the resources necessary to raise the girl to puberty. Richer men within the kin group can afford to pay the brideprice for more than one wife, and thus they ensure for themselves even greater returns on investment than those who cannot. As Schlegel and Eloul note, in such societies “the powerful man does not keep his wealth, but distributes it to acquire wives and in-laws.”30 This brideprice-with-polygyny-for-the-rich system is by far the most prevalent variant of patrilineality. Goody finds that 78 percent of the patrilineal cultures he has studied practice brideprice, and a further 6 percent practice bride-service, a variant thereof.31
The second, less frequent variant of dowry occurs in cases in which women are not valued for their productive labor; women are seen as a burden, and those who give the bride must be prepared to compensate the groom and his family for their assumption of this burden through payment of a dowry. Goody explains, “Bridewealth is more commonly found where women make the major contribution to agriculture, whereas dowry is restricted to those societies where males contribute most; this is the difference between hoe agriculture and the use of the plough, which is almost invariably in male hands.”32 Furthermore, one can also find societies in which dowry is practiced in higher socioeconomic classes, but brideprice is practiced among the poor. In such societies (and India is one), dowry among the rich becomes, in anthropologist John McCreery’s words, “a means of social mobility in stratified societies where men use rights over women, like other property, to compete for higher status.”33 In contrast, among the poor, especially in cases in which dowry has caused sex ratio alteration, the poor must pay for a bride.
The practice of brideprice differs from that of dowry in its effects on the status of women; tellingly, dowry is more often associated with female infanticide and sex-selective abortion, for families can be bankrupted by daughters whose dowries they must pay. The negative consequences of dowry on the lives of women are well-known. Demographer P. N. Mari Bhat and public health expert Shiva Halli write that in India, the “amount of dowry demanded has grown to a size that threatens the destitution of households with many daughters,”34 with up to two-thirds of total household assets going toward one daughter’s dowry in some places. Furthermore, they note that “while a large dowry does raise the prestige of the bride among her affines, more importantly, a small one can make her life miserable in the new home. The number of instances of such harassment that lead to either the suicide or murder of the helpless woman is increasing rapidly, and these cases frequently make newspaper headlines.”35
The effects of brideprice, in contrast to that of dowry, are less well recognized. In patrilineal systems, obligatory brideprice becomes a tax on young men, payable to older men. The young man’s father and male kindred may help him pay that tax, but the intergenerational nature of the tax should not be overlooked, especially in the case of poor young men whose father and kin may not be of much assistance for any number of reasons. Brideprice can be costly: in a recent article, the regional brideprices in Afghanistan ranged from a low of 100,000 afghanis to a high of 3 million afghanis (between $1,450 and $45,000). Furthermore, even though such a brideprice may be considered a mahr or dower that is supposed to be the property of the bride, this almost never occurs. This is a brideprice that almost always goes to the girl’s father or brother. As one man from Ghazni said,
On the day of my engagement in 2011, my father and brothers decided on a sum of 800,000 Pakistani rupees [about US$9,230] to be given as mahr to my future wife. The money was paid directly to her brother and after the wedding, when I asked my wife about the mahr, she told me that she did not receive a penny of the 800,000 [Pakistani] rupees. Instead, she told me that her brother had used the money to arrange the marriage of his son.36
Marriage is often delayed for men as they often must migrate to earn these sums, and marriage is often quite early for women as male relatives want the brideprice to pay for their own wedding costs, which means the age gap between spouses can be quite large.
The impact of wedding costs, even apart from brideprice or dowry, must also not be overlooked. In a recent New York Times article, Joseph Goldstein tells the tale of a thirty-one-year-old groom in Afghanistan who was a car salesman. On top of the brideprice, he was also expected to pay for a wedding that would feed well over six hundred people—most of whom he did not even know. The cost of his wedding was $30,000, and he would have to take out loans that would take him years to repay. When Afghanistan was considering a cap on the number of wedding guests at five hundred people (which bill passed in 2015), one young man expressed to Goldstein, “I demand that the president sign this law,” said Jawed (twenty-four years old), who sells fabric in a small stall in an underground shopping mall. “I beg him to sign this law as soon as possible so people like me can get married soon.”37
Brideprice has caused problems throughout Afghanistan’s history. Valentine Moghadam notes,
way back in 1978, the new left-wing government in what was then the Democratic Republic of Afghanistan decreed a limit to brideprice (walwar). This was one of the reasons for the tribal-Islamist uprising that began in the summer of 1978 (another was compulsory schooling, especially for girls). Stupidly and tragically, the DRA reforms were denigrated as “Sovietization” by outside detractors, including those in Human Rights Watch (like Jere Laber).38
The problem is so serious that several state governments have gotten involved in limiting these egregious wedding costs. For example, Tajikistan recently passed a law that allows the government to seize excess wedding items, such as food, and imposes a $4,000 fine for offenders. Tajik officials may be fired if they are found holding outsize weddings.39 The Saudi government has also been proactive, as well, in attempting to limit wedding costs.40
Why marry at all, then, if the brideprice is exorbitant? The logic of patrilineality demands marriage. As Farea Al-Muslimi comments about Yemen, “as soon as a young person reaches puberty, their only concern becomes marriage.”41 A man’s place in the agnatic lineage is only assured if he maintains that patriline into the future. Without a son, there is no one to inherit his position and his wealth, which will then devolve to his brothers and cousins. Without a son, there will be no one to take care of him in old age or to perform requisite religious rituals for his soul. If a man breaks the patrilineal chain, he cannot be regarded as an honorable part of the lineage group. For example, Monica Das Gupta notes about Korea,
[Ancestors] who died unmarried or without male descendants are filled with resentment and can create all kinds of problems for their siblings and other kin. It is apparent that there is much pressure from a wide range of family members to ensure that each individual performs their filial duties of marrying and bearing sons quickly, and caring for their ancestors.42
Therefore, even if brideprice or dowry is high, young men will strive mightily to marry and produce sons. Important in understanding the consequences of brideprice is the evidence that brideprice acts as a flat tax—for the most part, brideprice is the same “going rate” within the society. The brideprice is nudged slightly upward or downward at the margin according to the status of the bride’s kin, but it is not affected greatly by the status of the man responsible for paying it. If the cost of brideprice rises, it will rise for every man, rich or poor. The flat-tax nature of brideprice is independent of geographic region; studies conducted in Afghanistan, China, and Kenya found that regardless of socioeconomic class, young men are expected to pay the same price to get married.
The tendency toward a consistent brideprice is easily understood. Goody suggests, “in bridewealth systems, standard payments are more common; their role in a societal exchange puts pressure towards similarity.”43 The reason for this is that men pay for their sons’ brideprices by collecting the brideprice for their daughters. This is another force pushing down girls’ age of marriage. In a given family, unless it is very wealthy, daughters in general must be married off first so that the family can accumulate enough assets to pay the sons’ brideprices. Quoting anthropologist Lucy Mair, Goody remarks, “ ‘when cattle payments are made, the marriage of girls tends to be early for the same reason that that of men is late—that a girl’s marriage increases her father’s herd while that of a young man diminishes it’…Men chafe at the delay, girls at the speed.”44 If brideprice were variable within a society, families could not count on the brideprices brought in by their daughters to be sufficient to fulfill the obligation they owe their sons. Thus, over time, a fairly consistent brideprice emerges for the community at any given time, although the actual cost may trend upward or downward over time depending on local conditions.
Indeed, many accounts suggest that men are sensitive to any new trends in brideprice, and the societal brideprice level is easily pushed upward. Quoting Mair again, Goody notes “Every father fears being left in the lurch by finding that the bridewealth which he has accepted for his daughter will not suffice to get him a daughter-in-law; therefore he is always on the lookout for any signs of a rise in the rate, and tends to raise his demands whenever he hears of other fathers doing so. This mean in general terms, that individual cases of over-payment produce a general rise in the rate all around.”45 This is true even in the case in which governments try to cap brideprices to stop this inexorable inflation; for example in Niger, even though the government has placed a cap of 50,000 CFA francs on brideprices, in practice families pay far more than this amount.46 (The attempt to cap brideprice can be a catalyst for rebellion, as we saw in the case of the attempted reforms in the Democratic Republic of Afghanistan in the 1970s, which was a catalyst for insurgency.) Poorer men who must delay marriage to save up enough to marry may find that brideprices have also risen over time, making their endeavors to “catch up” impossible in the end; this phenomenon also has been noted in China.47
Exigency plays a role in the sudden rises and sudden falls of brideprice. Brideprice can collapse precipitously in times of exigency—for example, Yemen’s civil war has caused just such a collapse. Before the civil war, a brideprice of 1 million Yemeni rials was standard (about $4,650). After the war was underway, the going price dropped to about 300,000 Yemeni rials. Although some families never considered marrying their daughters for such a low price, and refused to have them married as a result, other families were concerned whether their daughters would be able to marry at all and took the lower price.48 When they took the lower price, they lowered the price for all, causing on overall collapse in price. Steep inflation in brideprice can also occur as a result of exigency, for example, from abnormal sex ratios. The Economist reports that brideprice in rural China has increased dramatically over the past decade, from about 3,000 yuan to more than 300,000 yuan as a result of the increasing scarcity of brides.49
As noted, brideprice is associated with early age of marriage for girls, because that practice ensures that men may accumulate capital to purchase wives. Women’s economic value as wives, when added to their value as marriageable daughters, allows for the accumulation of wealth to bring in more wives. As a result, the sale of daughters tends to take place as early as practicable, pushing down the age of marriage for girls. As Goody remarks, “Polygyny…is made possible by the differential marriage age, early for girls, later for men. Bridewealth and polygyny play into each other’s hands…the two institutions appear to reinforce each other.”50 We have already noted that this polygynous tendency will be exaggerated in societies in which women perform a substantial proportion of productive labor, such as farm labor. Buying additional wives is thus one route to increased wealth through accumulating a larger labor force. Polygyny is also a marker of higher status within the society, and is sought after for display of that higher status, as well, even in societies in which women’s labor is not valuable (such as in the United Arab Emirates).
Given the social utility and centrality of marriage in these patrilineal contexts, brideprice is not a luxury tax affecting the budgets of the elite, but rather it is more akin to a regressive tax that disproportionately affects the poor and middle class. This places a heavy economic burden on young men—particularly in situations of economic stagnation, rising inequality, or brideprice inflation. A summary of the average brideprice from a number of different periods and countries found that the burden equated to as much as twelve to twenty times the per capita holdings of large livestock or two to four times gross household income.51 We will explore the societal effects of such a strain in chapter 5 of this volume.
Polygyny
Polygyny, that is having formal or recognized marriages with two or more women, is not uncommon in today’s world (figure 3.5). Indeed, Rose McDermott and Jonathan Cowden suggest that it exists “in more than 83 percent of 849 cultures worldwide,” and note that “everywhere the practice is more widespread among high-status, high-wealth men.”52 Polyandry, virtually never practiced in human societies, is a practice of the very poor and is usually fraternal, that is, where brothers share a wife because they are too poor to afford the brideprices required for each one to marry separately. It is telling that even in cultures with traces of polyandry, rich men will still take multiple wives.
FIGURE 3.5 Map of the Prevalence and Legal Status of Polygyny, scaled 2016
Although most prevalent in Sub-Saharan Africa and Islamic-majority countries, polygyny in some areas is creeping back in after decades of suppression, such as in post-Soviet Central Asia or in areas with high numbers of widows because of warfare.53 Polygyny is easily effected by wealthy elites in brideprice societies. As Goody notes, “Bridewealth [i.e., brideprice] and dowry have different potentialities in the way they can link up with the politico-economic institutions of the society where they are found. Bridewealth can neatly tie in with polygyny.”54
Polygyny serves two distinct functions. It is most widely known today as a marker of elite status, as only the wealthy will be able to afford to pay multiple brideprices. Polygyny also cements more than one political alliance among the various leaders of male kin groups. Such marriage alliances are more durable and more likely to deter internecine conflict than those not sealed by marriage and offspring.55 Anthropologist Thomas Barfield notes, “marriage ties created patterns of alliances that crosscut the seemingly rigid set of patrilineal relationships within a conical clan. For this reason, polygynous marriages by tribal rulers were common.”56
Status is also displayed in the formation of these alliances; for example, social anthropologists Madawi Al-Rasheed and Loulouwa Al-Rasheed observe that when the house of Saud won out over the Rashidis, they smoothed relations by marrying Rashidi women in polygynous circumstances, but they never allowed Saudi women to marry Rashidi men, for “wife-givers” are in status inferior to “wife-takers.”57 As a status marker, polygyny is an effective means of raising one’s status even when one’s birth status is not extraordinary. As Goody notes, brideprice has “a leveling function,”58 by which he means that as long as a man has the requisite assets, in many cases he can marry a comparatively high-status woman regardless of his own family’s social standing.
This type of elite polygynous marriage as a status marker can occur in various types of economic systems. Polygyny, however, takes on a special cast in societies in which agriculture is the primary source of wealth and in which women are the primary agricultural laborers. In such societies, polygyny arises as an effective means of improving the rate and the absolute amount of wealth accumulation for a subset of men. Goody notes, “Polygyny is found where women make a substantial contribution to productive activity, especially to cultivation.”59 Marrying more women increases the amount of land that can be profitably cultivated, and surplus income can even be used to marry additional wives.
The effects of polygyny on women and their children are as profound as those of brideprice and dowry. Unless the family is so wealthy that resources are bounteous, polygyny significantly depresses investment in women and children beyond the initial investment in the acquisition of the wives involved. Numerous studies have demonstrated that significantly less attention is paid to the health (physical and mental), nutrition, and education of women and children in polygynous households.60 Richard Alexander notes that a man may trade off investment in his offspring for the ability to purchase additional wives as a reproductive strategy.61
McDermott and Cowden find a statistically significant relationship between the legality and prevalence of polygyny within a country, on the one hand, and what they call “an entire downstream suite of negative consequences for men, women, children, and the nation-state,” on the other.62 Their data analysis points to a significant relationship between polygyny and unequal family law, higher birth rates, rates of primary and secondary education for both male and female children, HIV infection, low age of marriage for girls, high maternal mortality, lower life expectancy, higher levels of sex trafficking, and higher levels of domestic violence. The evolutionary psychologist Satoshi Kanazawa has also found lower age of menarche.63 Other experts have pointed to psychological harms for women and children in polygynous marriages, including anxiety and depression.64 This anxiety and depression may not only be felt by women (and their children) already in polygynous relationships but also by women (and their children) currently in monogamous relationships, who must worry about whether their husband and father will take additional wives. In a cross-cultural sample, Barash finds that 90 percent of polygynously married women reported sexual and emotional conflict, particularly involving children and the allocation of resources within the household.65
McDermott and Cowden also note that polygyny often creates a class of unmarriageable young men. In the polygynist communities in the western United States and Canada among the Fundamentalist Church of Jesus Christ of Latter-Day Saints (FLDS), a group splintered off from the Mormon Church that still practices polygyny, they are called the “Lost Boys,” for they are thrust out of their communities.66 For wealthy men to have many wives, a sizeable number of young men must have none. As we detail in chapter 5, this may catalyze instability and even conflict. In addition to the substantial risk of being crowded out of the marriage market, Barash notes that sons in polygynous cultures are affected in other ways, as well. For example, sons often are socialized to be highly competitive and aggressive in polygynous cultures.67
Polygyny reliably produces harms for children. We have noted McDermott and Cowden’s findings on lower rates of primary and secondary education for girls and boys, but the literature finds consistent underinvestment overall in the children of polygynous unions. The evolutionary biologist Joseph Henrich asserts that “polygynous men invest less in their offspring both because they have more offspring and because they continue to invest in seeking additional wives. This implies that, on average, children in a more polygynous society will receive less parental investment.”68 Henrich and his coauthors cite several studies showing that in both West Africa and East Africa, children in polygynous households had significantly higher death rates and significantly poorer nutrition than children in monogamous households.69 For example, among the polygynous Dogon tribe of Mali, a child born to a polygynous family is seven to eleven times more likely to die early than one born to a monogamous couple; among the Temne of Sierra Leone, the mortality rate among children born into polygyny was found to be 41 percent, compared with 25 percent for those born into monogamy.70 Fascinatingly, they also note that the survival rates among nineteenth-century Mormon children in Utah were actually lower for wealthier families that practiced polygyny than for poor families that did not. Even among the modern FLDS, rampant child labor, malnourishment, physical abuse, and inbreeding all take a tremendous physical and emotional toll.71 Because of all of these demonstrable harms, Canada has upheld the constitutionality of a ban on polygamy in both 2011 and 2018.72 We outline additional consequences of polygyny in chapters 4 and 5 as we trace the effects of the Syndrome’s components on the larger social order.
Patrilocality is a natural extension of the logic of patrilineality as a system of security provision (figure 3.6). Male blood relatives stay together to provide the requisite fraternal alliance, and it is women who must move to bring about the needed exogamy that will prevent genetic disaster. Women move out of their natal home and go to live with their husband’s kin group. In some cases, they may never see their birth family again.73 Economist Louise Grogan estimates that at least 70 percent of human societies practice patrilocal marriage.74
FIGURE 3.6 Map of the Prevalence of Patrilocal Marriage, scaled 2016
Avraham Ebenstein argues that the logic of patrilocality reaches its zenith when the chief inheritable asset is land. He asserts:
The adoption of patrilocal norms serves to keep the son close for defense, to provide him wealth to support one or more wives, and to care for his elderly parents in their old age…and sons need their fathers’ land. Often, this implicit barter will be further reinforced by religious norms that develop to enforce the agreement, such as Confucianism’s focus on filial piety, or the need for a son to pray for the dead in Hinduism…. The elders become the holders of capital, and can exchange this for their children’s labor, mediated through a norm of coresidence.75
Although inheritable land drives patrilocal norms in some cultures, it is also true that nomadic tribes often practice patrilocality as well, and for many of the same reasons, such as defense by the extended male kin group. We suggest it is necessary to examine the prevalence of brideprice in connection with patrilocality, for the need to produce brideprice also fuels the need to consolidate (as versus disperse) patriline assets, and again this favors patrilocal norms.
As with brideprice or dowry and polygyny, the effects of patrilocal marriage on women are detrimental. Patrilocality typically cuts off a woman from sources of kin support that may serve to protect and sustain her. In fact, her birth family may come to see investment in her as a daughter as meaningless, for she will soon depart from their midst to join her husband’s family.76 We find proverbs from all over the patrilocal world that demonstrate this attitude: “Raising a daughter is like watering a plant in another man’s garden,” “A daughter is a thief,” “A daughter is but a houseguest.” This may help explain other norms, such as differential feeding practices for daughters and sons, and differential investment in health and education.
Once this “outsider” reaches her new home with her husband’s family, she is likely to face more differential treatment—as well as suspicion and perhaps even abuse. This predisposition actually may be augmented by the payment of brideprice, which may be taken by some to mean that the girl has been bought, and thus she has the status of a chattel. As Xie Lihua of Rural Women’s Magazine in China put it, “there’s a saying among men: ‘marrying a woman is like buying a horse: I can ride you and beat you whenever I like.’ Men feel that ‘I’ve spent money on bringing you into my family, so I have the right to order you around.’ And a man will beat a woman if she has a mind of her own.”77
In addition to physical consequences, there are also profound psychological consequences for the woman. Where, exactly, is her home, that is, her place of safety and acceptance? It appears not to be either in her parents’ home or in her in-laws’ home. What is her central love relationship? It is not to be found in her birth family, and it is not with her husband. Rather, her only lasting love relationship is with her son, if she produces one, which accounts for the deep tension between mother-in-law and daughter-in-law when that son marries. It also accounts for intensified son preference; as Grogan notes, “Sons are the key intergenerational link where women move to their husband’s natal residence upon marriage.”78
Furthermore, the patrilocal nature of marriage puts the woman at risk should she be widowed or divorced. A widow may be subject to levirate marriage (marriage to her dead husband’s brother or other near kin), or she simply may be ousted from the household by her in-laws and left to forage for herself. She may not be able to inherit as a widow from her husband in some cultures, with all his property reverting to the patriline. A woman who is divorced may also lose custody of her children, because they are considered to be affines of her husband’s family, and she may not be able to return to her birth family, either, leaving her without a place to live.
Although urbanization attenuates patrilocality, the practice can return after decades of more neolocal marriage norms. For example, Grogan notes that after the fall of the Soviet Union, economic shocks and rising instability catalyzed a return to a patrilocal marriage norm in nations such as Tajikistan.79 Again, we see that reversion to the security provision mechanism of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome as the result of exigency will also cause a regress in the situation of women at the household level.
Son Preference and Sex Ratios
A discussion of son preference and sex ratios naturally follows from a discussion of brideprice, polygyny, and patrilocality (figure 3.7). Son preference follows from patrilineality as one more logical extension. From all that we have learned, it is clear that the “true members” of a kin group are the males in the patriline, and for a man to continue that kin line is obligatory for him to have full standing in the group and to be able to pass an inheritance to his own posterity and not to his brothers. That means he must have a son; a daughter will simply not suffice. Although daughters may be valued for their instrumental usefulness in bringing in a brideprice, or for their productive or reproductive labor, only sons have existential value and thus merit sustained investment in their nutrition, health care, and education. Only sons are a bridge to the future for a patriline; only sons bring to their fathers a permanent standing in the lineage group.
FIGURE 3.7 Map of Son Preference and Childhood Sex Ratios, scaled 2015
Intense son preference can lead to high fertility and high maternal mortality rates in some societies. One Afghan woman was interviewed by the Afghan Women’s Writing Project in the Herat Maternity Clinic, and offered her story:
First I talk to a woman who tells me about her life with tears pouring from her eyes. Wounds on her face show she has recently been beaten. She cannot tell me much, she is afraid and cannot say her name to me, but she talks about her life. She does not tell her age; she says only that she was the youngest in her family. She is pregnant with her ninth child. She has eight children who are all girls, and in three months her next child will be born. She says her husband’s family forced her to continue to become pregnant to give birth to a boy and she says this time she knows she will have a son because the pregnancy feels different from the other times. All of her children were born at home and she came to the clinic only because of bleeding. Her husband had beaten her. She says if she does not bear a son her husband will end their marriage and will abandon her with her daughters.80
Part of the calculus of son preference is that because of patrilocality, only sons provide old age insurance for elderly parents. Daughters will be leaving to live with their husband’s family, but sons will stay and are responsible for the care of elderly parents. As Das Gupta notes, “Son preference is found in certain types of cultures, that is, patrilineal cultures…[where] daughters are formally transferred on marriage to their husband’s family and can no longer contribute to their natal family. This drastically lowers the value of daughters relative to sons, reducing parents’ willingness to invest in raising girls.”81
Thus, we are not surprised to find that patrilocal norms are strongly associated with abnormally high sex ratios favoring males.82 That is, these norms incentivize both the bearing of sons and the prevention of the birth of daughters either through female infanticide or sex-selective abortion. Ebenstein notes this connection, stating
parents abort girls because of patrilocality: [patrilocality] is the single common factor across countries with high sex ratios, and as such, should be viewed as the primary factor in explaining the phenomenon. Patrilocality is the single feature common to the social norms of Christians in Armenia, Muslims in Azerbaijan, Hindus in India and Buddhists in China—all live with their sons when they are old…every country with abnormally high sex ratios at birth in the samples has a high proportion of elderly living with sons.83
Ebenstein shows empirically that even when controlling for measures of gender equity, such as education and employment rates, groups where sons live with their parents have higher sex ratios. His analysis is revealing; he finds that even where women are not otherwise disadvantaged in education or employment, such as in Armenia or China, if the elderly typically coreside with sons, high sex ratios are manifest.84
Armenia is a telling case in Ebenstein’s view, because sex ratios in that country were absolutely normal until the collapse of the Soviet Union. Ebenstein notes that after that event, “Parents realized that old age support would be provided by the family rather than the state.”85 He found that, consequently, sex ratios rose to 53.1 percent male among lower-income Armenians. He posits that this socioeconomic class began to demonstrate son preference to ensure care later in life because they could rely on neither their savings nor the state to provide it. “The Armenian experience documents the dangers facing policymakers when social protections are removed among parents who have access to sex selection technology,” he explains.86
Armenia is not the only post–Soviet era nation seeing a resurgence in male-skewed sex ratios. Azerbaijan, Georgia, Montenegro, and Albania all have seen increased sex ratios, with Georgia clocking in at an estimated 122 boys per 100 girls born in the 2000–2005 period.87 The birth sex ratio in Armenia hit 114.4 in 2011, and Azerbaijan’s was 115.5.88 Furthermore, political scientist Andrea Den Boer also notes excess female mortality in the first few years of life, as well, indicating passive infanticide of girls. (Ironically, the chronic housing shortage in the Soviet Union contributed to the continued cultural practice of patrilocality in this region, according to Den Boer.)
Patrilineal societies typically fuse religious belief with the importance of the patriline, and therefore it is not unexpected to find religious or quasi-religious beliefs supporting son preference. For example, in China, Das Gupta notes,
It is believed that one’s own soul and that of one’s male ancestors need to be cared for by male progeny, without which the dead will become what in China is called “hungry ghosts.” No pension plan can cover care in the afterlife. Angering the ancestors through unfilial acts can bring their wrath down on you in this life, bringing supernatural sanctions and bad luck. Not bearing a son is a major dereliction of filial duty.89
Sex ratio alteration is a telling indicator of women’s disempowerment at the household level. Economist Andrew Francis notes that “the incidence of selective abortion, infanticide, and neglect [of females] is inversely related to women’s intra-household bargaining power. Empowering women, wives and mothers, reduces the number of ‘missing’ women.”90 Indeed, the fact that it is often mothers-in-law who most directly pressure daughters-in-law to get rid of female offspring is a testament to just how disempowered women are, indicating that only the birth of sons lifts a woman’s status in the home, even among other women.
The toll on women’s health of son preference can be appalling; public health expert Narjis Rizvi and colleagues conducted thirty focus groups of 250 women in Pakistan, finding that many of the women indicated that they “continue bearing children until the family has at least one son; she sometimes delivers 7 or more daughters in order to accomplish the objective…. Except the post-delivery period in case of the male baby, when higher allowances are given so that the boy can be breastfed, generally meager nutritional allocation and repeated pregnancies make them malnourished.”91
Interestingly, unless other Syndrome components are present to prevent it, masculinized sex ratios can actually increase women’s bargaining power within the home. That is, in a context in which potential wives are relatively scarce, if women are relatively free to choose whether to marry and have access to divorce, custody, and property rights in marriage, empirical research suggests that, once married, they are able to bargain for greater investment in the children of the marriage (e.g., greater number of years of schooling) as well as ensure lower rates of infanticide, sex-selective abortion and neglect of daughters, and achieve lower total fertility.92 For example, in China, one young man interviewed by the China Youth Daily noted, “In my hometown, the status of the wife and her mother-in-law has reversed, especially in a family with bad finances. The mother-in-law needs to treat the wife carefully in order to avoid the wife leaving the family. It’s not the wife that the mother-in-law truly cares about, it’s [the brideprice].”93 In most Syndrome-encoded societies, however, this situation rarely occurs. Indeed, one could propose that the interlocking straitjacket of the Syndrome purposefully serves, among many other things, to effectively insulate men and their patriline from any such development.
Abnormal sex ratios play havoc with brideprice, as we discussed earlier. As one Chinese matchmaker put it, “The scarcity of marriageable women makes men like a starving man—all food is delicious to them.”94 As brideprice rises beyond the reach of many men, they may seek divorced women or women with mental or physical disabilities, for the brideprice will be considerably lower for these women. Families with several sons may be able to fund only the marriage of the eldest. One family in Hubei, China, with four sons, decided that the four brothers would have to jointly raise enough money for the eldest to marry and that the rest would probably have to forgo any hope of marrying at all.95
Abnormal sex ratios are not a thing of the past; indeed, they are spreading. In 1990, five nation-states had abnormal sex ratios in early childhood (ages birth to four years old); now there are nineteen (twenty-one, if you include Hong Kong and Macau). In 1990, the phenomenon was confined to Asia, but now the countries with abnormal sex ratios across ages birth to four years old include many outside that continent, including Albania, Armenia, Azerbaijan, China, Hong Kong, Macau, Egypt, Fiji, Georgia, India, Kosovo, Kuwait, Lebanon, Montenegro, Philippines, South Sudan, Sudan, Taiwan, Macedonia, Vanuatu, and Vietnam.96 Expatriate communities may also create enclaves of higher sex ratios; for example, in Canada, Indian-born women with two daughters have a birth sex ratio for their third child of 196 boys per 100 girls.97
Migration can create age-cohort pockets of abnormal sex ratios,98 as has been noted in Sweden after the mass migration of 2015, subsequent to which the sex ratio of sixteen- and seventeen-year-olds in Sweden rose to 123 males per 100 females, far surpassing the sex ratio of China for the same age cohort (117:100). Furthermore, historical path dependencies may be at work—for example, researchers have tied modern West African polygyny to a legacy of abnormal sex ratios resulting from slavery, where about two-thirds of those exported as slaves from West Africa were male.99
The devaluation of female life, expressed most starkly in female infanticide and sex-selective abortion, is interwoven with the history of female subordination stretching back millennia. As Gerda Lerner notes, “One of the first powers men institutionalized under patriarchy was the power of the male head of the family to decide which infants should live and which infants should die. This power must have been perceived as a victory of law over nature, for it went directly against nature and previous human experience.”100 Indeed, as the current estimate of the number of missing women in Asia alone rises inexorably toward two hundred million,101 it is astonishing that the world considers this toll, which dwarfs that of any war, so unremarkable—and so unrelated to national and international security. In part II, we explain how wrong that mind-set proves to be.
Low Age of First Marriage for Girls
Estimates are that almost five million girls are married annually at younger than sixteen years of age (figure 3.8).102 These young girls are, for the most part, not marrying men of the same age: the average difference in age is six years, with the husband being substantially older. In Niger, for example, 59 percent of child brides married a man at least ten years older; the corresponding figure for Bolivia was 46 percent. The United Nations Population Fund notes that 19 percent of young women in developing countries become pregnant before the age of eighteen, and 95 percent of those births occur within marriage. Furthermore, 2 million of the 7.3 million births every year to adolescents are to those who are younger than age fifteen—in some countries, that represents 10 percent of under-fifteen girls.103
FIGURE 3.8 Map of Age of Marriage for Girls in Law and Practice, scaled 2015
Patrilineality tends to be associated with a low age of marriage for girls, even child marriage. This is largely because daughters hold less value compared with sons in patrilineal culture; daughters marry exogamously and therefore are not considered full members of the kin group, but they must be fed, clothed, and housed before marriage; preserving the sexual purity of daughters becomes more onerous to the family with each year past puberty; and daughters may bring in a good-size brideprice upon marriage, which subsequently could be used to contract marriages for the men of the family. Child marriage for girls minimizes expenditures and expedites income that may be needed to pay for the marriages of the more important sons. In addition, child marriage for girls may reduce threats to the family’s honor (and hoped-for brideprice) by reducing the time period in which she is vulnerable to sexual predation.
Exigencies also increase the rate of child marriage for girls. Whether as a result of natural disaster or conflict, crisis will push down the age of marriage as families are scrambling for resources and are willing to marry off girls in exchange. In addition, in desperate situations caused by having to flee conflicts, families may feel completely unable to protect their girls from sexual predation, and marriage may seem the best way to preserve their honor. This dynamic is playing out as we speak among refugees from the Syrian conflict. Save the Children reports,
Child marriage existed in Syria before the crisis—13 percent of girls under 18 in Syria were married in 2011. But now, three years into the conflict, official statistics show that among Syrian refugee communities in Jordan…child marriage has increased alarmingly, and in some cases has doubled. In Jordan, the proportion of registered marriages among the Syrian refugee community where the bride was under 18 rose from 12 percent in 2011 (roughly the same as the figure in pre-war Syria) to 18 percent in 2012, and as high as 25 percent by 2013. The number of Syrian boys registered as married in 2011 and 2012 in Jordan is far lower, suggesting that girls are, as a matter of course, being married off to older males.104
The same phenomenon is observable in Yemen’s civil war, as well, and Oxfam has asserted that girls as young as three years of age are being married off to obtain brideprice to feed the rest of the family.105
Interestingly, a new exigency for modern parents is that educated girls may refuse to marry a partner they deem unacceptable, or they may refuse to marry at all. Marrying daughters off early may prevent such insubordination from occurring. Louisa Chiang notes, “Reversing a long-running trend, some rural families now marry off their daughters earlier, enticed by the high brideprice and concerned that older, more educated daughters are likely to leave or are harder to dictate marriage terms to.”106 The highly masculinized sex ratio pushes down the age of marriage for women, as witnessed by the resurgence of early marriage in China despite laws against such practices.107
Another type of family exigency is debt or blood debt; in certain cultures, girls may be “gifted” to pay such a debt. In Afghanistan the tradition is known as baad, and it is estimated that more than 10 percent of marriages in that country stem from the practice. The Afghan Penal Code supposedly prohibits baad, but only for women over eighteen years old and widows. Virtually all those given in baad are young girls, however.108
The effects on girls of child marriage are devastating. We will argue in later chapters that the effects on the broader society are equally devastating. For the girls, however, gender and foreign policy expert Rachel Vogelstein notes they are “forced to leave their families, marry against their will, endure sexual and physical abuse, and bear children while still in childhood…it is tantamount to sexual slavery.”109 Woe unto the girl who wishes to escape her fate:
A child bride’s instinct to run away is often met with horrific consequences. If a child bride leaves her husband’s home, she risks retaliation from both her husband’s family and her birth family. For the bride’s family, having a daughter that has run away from her husband’s home brings shame onto the entire family. The bride’s virtue is automatically called into question, and she is labeled as promiscuous and disobedient. Ultimately, the perceived shame for the birth family will become unbearable, until finally, a male in the family will seek to bring back the family’s honor by killing the source of the pain: the young bride…Thirteen-year-old Yemeni child bride Ilham Mahdi al Assi died tragically three days after her wedding in April, after she was tied down, raped repeatedly and left bleeding to death. Another recent example is 12-year-old Fawziya Abdullah Youssef, also a Yemeni child bride, who died after three days of excruciating labor pain because her body wasn’t developed enough to give birth.110
Child marriage clearly does not serve the interests of the girls involved in terms of their physical health, opportunities for education, or level of safety within the household. As a United Nations Children's Fund report summarizes, “Child marriage is a violation of human rights, compromising the development of girls and often resulting in early pregnancy and social isolation. Young married girls face onerous domestic burdens, constrained decision-making and reduced life choices.”111
One of the most important feedback loops with in the Syndrome is between child marriage, brideprice or dowry, and violence against women. Vogelstein reports:
Data from India show that girls married at age eighteen or older are more likely to repudiate domestic violence, whereas those married under the age of eighteen are more likely to have experience with physical or sexual abuse. Girls married as children are also more likely to be physically abused not only by their husbands, but also by their family members and in-laws. Wide disparities in age and power between husband and wife, as well as marital financial transactions such as dowry and brideprice, can exacerbate social norms that sanction violence.”112
Child marriage produces many cascading effects on human and economic security, which we detail in chapter 6. World Bank economist Quentin Wodon summarizes them here:
By curtailing education, increasing fertility, and limiting opportunities for employment, child marriage contributes to poverty. The practice is also associated with a higher risk of intimate partner violence and other forms of violence, which may lead to severe injuries and even death, as well as losses in earnings and out-of-pocket costs for healthcare. Next, child marriage is associated with higher risks of…maternal mortality and morbidity…malnutrition and depression [and] poor sexual and reproductive health outcomes including through sexually transmitted diseases. The practice also has consequences for children in terms of infant mortality, low birth weight, and stunting. Finally, child marriage also leads to losses in empowerment and decision-making as well as participation more generally.113
But these statistics may obscure the sheer enormity of the human cost.114 As Stephanie Sinclair, the award-winning photographer whose photos of child brides put a shocking face to these statistics, reflects,
I first encountered child marriage in Afghanistan in 2003. I was horrified to learn that several girls in one province had set themselves on fire. After some investigation, it became apparent that one of the things propelling these girls to commit such a drastic act was having been forced to marry as a child. They told me they’d been married at 9, 10, 11—and in their misery [they] had preferred death over the lives they were living…. Every girl I met, in each country, completely broke my heart—particularly the ones married to much older men. The more I pursued the phenomenon, the more the issue continued to unravel before me. The trauma these girls carry with them into adulthood is utterly palpable when speaking with child marriage survivors about their experiences. These heroic women live their lives just like anyone else, but if they’re comfortable enough to discuss their past with you, the toll taken by such an intense childhood trauma becomes very, very clear. Then you take the experiences of the relative handful of girls and survivors I’ve met and then realize…with child marriage occurring in more than 50 countries worldwide, how many more girls are living a similar hell, day in and day out. The numbers are staggering! At least 39,000 girls married every day—that’s one girl every two seconds! Every day that goes by, an incomprehensible number of girls’ lives have been forever changed.115
And not for the better. As one health-care worker put it in Morocco, “This type of marriage is child rape; that is to say, her life has been raped by means of this marriage.”116 The incidence of child marriage is falling worldwide, except in Latin America where rates are rising.117 Even so, gains have been painfully slow. For example, a legal change in Morocco designed to reduce the number of girl-child marriages has unintentionally increased the number.118 Furthermore, as noted by Vogelstein, “The failure of some governments to implement systems of birth and marriage registration also makes it easier to avoid compliance with minimum age of marriage laws.”119 As we have seen, any type of exigency may catalyze child marriage for girls, for the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome rigidly encodes their lower value as well as their higher risk to family honor. In November 2014, the Human Rights Committee of the United Nations General Assembly adopted by consensus a resolution calling on all nations to end child marriage and forced marriage. The resolution had 118 sponsors from across all continents—but the map at the beginning of this subsection tells the true tale.
Cousin Marriage
Cousin marriage is common in some patrilineal societies as a way to keep assets within the family—that is, so that brideprice or dowry does not leave the family when a woman marries (figure 3.9).120 Reciprocal exchange of daughters between kin, or “bride exchange,” with marriage often to one’s father’s brother’s daughter, often occurs in this context to maintain roughly equal status between the cousins’ families, for in patrilineal societies, as Goody explains, “[There is a] strong tendency for the wife-receiving group to rank the higher.”121 Reciprocal exchange of women within the kin group prevents this status difference from emerging.
FIGURE 3.9 Map of Prevalence and Legality of Cousin Marriage, scaled 2016
Anthropologist Bernard Chapais and others believe cross-cousin marriage developed early in human society, perhaps even in the prelinguistic era. Interestingly, he posits its rationale is the construction of what he terms “affinal brotherhood,” that is, linking a brother (and his father) through the brother’s sister to her husband, maintaining affinity across the branches of the patriline. This brotherhood-through-marriage permits “male pacification,” by which Chapais means reduction in competition and violence between men “connected” by women.122 This brotherhood then forms the basis of the larger community, the agnatic tribe, whose boundaries are circumscribed by how far across the genealogical tree one may marry.
The presence of cousin marriage is a tip-off that patrilineality is present, for without patrilineality, there would be no incentive for it, especially given the genetic risks that are disproportionately present in cases in which cousin marriage is practiced. One Egyptian pediatrician asserts that 90 percent of the genetic diseases seen in children in that country are the result of consanguineous marriage, and include microcephaly, cystic fibrosis, thalassaemia, and previously unseen disorders.123 In the United Kingdom, where it is estimated that 60 percent of couples of Pakistani heritage are in consanguineous marriages, the death rate attributed to inherited disease was thirty-eight times that of reference couples.124 In Egypt, about 40 percent marry cousins, and rates are similar for Jordan and also the Gulf states. Iran’s rate of cousin marriage is approximately 37 percent.125 Across the MENA region as a whole, up to 50 percent of marriages may be consanguineous.126 The toll of misery from genetic disease is appallingly high in all these countries.
Even so, in Saudi Arabia, there is a saying concerning cousin marriage that, “a piece of fabric remains beautiful only if the additional fabric attached to it is from the same kind.”127 Abdul Al Lily describes how some Saudi tribes will reject marriage proposals from nonfamily members and even will decide on marriage partners from among the cousins for a child at the time of their birth. Oftentimes even an ominous genetic test result between cousins may not preclude the marriage.128
Cousin marriage not only is prevalent in MENA but also is practiced among some groups in South Asia. Hanan Jacoby and Ghazala Mansuri reference a 2004–2005 survey in the Pakistani provinces of Sindh and Punjab, finding that more than three-quarters of women had married a blood relative, typically a cousin.129 It is also not uncommon for cousin marriage to be reciprocal, that is, female cousins are exchanged between kin so that no money or assets need change hands, and even the women’s inheritances are kept within their birth families. (Sometimes such a “swap” can even take place between families that are not kin, although our scale of cousin marriage does not capture that practice.) “Swapping” women can sometimes be risky, however, because if one of the marriages ends in divorce, the other couple may be forced to divorce, as well—even if they are happy together—for reasons of honor.130 If one wife is killed through domestic violence, the other may be killed, as well, in retribution. An additional catalyst besides preservation of patriline assets is the often-fierce rivalry between male cousins, which this type of marriage is meant to ameliorate.131
In historical Europe, as well, patrilineal elites often sought special dispensation from the Catholic Church to marry cousins, again to conserve status and assets through endogamy. However, cousin marriage violated the Church’s ban on incest—defined as marriage or sexual relations within four to seven degrees of separation, depending on the time period examined. Goody explains that “property was key” to understanding these marriages, which often took place among elites and nobles.132 Indeed, he further suggests that in the context in which land is the key asset, cousin marriage in the context of patrilineality will almost always develop, noting that “the possession of livestock does not lead to quite the same pressure for status preservation and endogamy as occurs in systems of intensive farming.”133
Cousin marriage may ameliorate some of the emotional distance between a bride and her natal family, offering a sense of bilaterality and perhaps providing stronger protections for the bride. Harming a bride from a nonrelated family is one thing, but harming a bride from your uncle’s family is quite another. Tanika Chakraborty and Sukkoo Kim propose that “women’s bargaining position seems to be higher in societies where cross-cousin marriages are allowed than in societies that restrict marriages to non-kin. Because women marry into familiar kin networks rather than to strange families, they are likely to have more allies. Women’s property rights are positively correlated with marriages in which women are in close proximity to their natal home, which is often the case in cross-cousin marriages.”134
Unfortunately, this proposition may not hold in real life. For example, despite the authors hearing from numerous interviewees in societies that practice endogamy that the practice offers physical protection for the bride, it is also true that economist Alberto Alesina and coauthors find that “being from an ethnicity that was traditionally endogamous is positively associated with violence experienced, increasing the likelihood of ever being victim of violence by 6.9 percentage points, a 26 percent increase over the mean. This is accompanied by a positive and significant effect on the reported male acceptability of violence towards women.”135
In sum, then, the practice of cousin marriage produces not only avoidable devastating genetic consequences, but also firmly asserts the patriline’s interest over that of the woman involved. She may have little say in whom she marries and may have very little chance of escaping an abusive marriage because it has been arranged by the entire kin network in its own strategic interest. Lerner describes the logic of cousin marriage well when she writes,
The “exchange of women”…is always preceded…by the indoctrination of women, from earliest childhood on, to an acceptance of their obligation to their kin to consent to such enforced marriages. [Quoting Levi-Strauss] “The total relationship of exchange which constitutes marriage is not established between a man and a woman…but between two groups of men, and the woman figures only as one of the objects in the exchange, not as one of the partners…This remains true even when the girl’s feelings are taken into consideration, as, moreover, is usually the case. In acquiescing to the proposed union, she precipitates or allows the exchange to take place; she cannot alter its nature.”136
Inequity in Family Law and Practice
In their work analyzing responses from the World Value Survey, political scientists Ronald Inglehart and Pippa Norris uncovered an unusual finding: there was little cross-national variation in the degree to which survey respondents valued democracy and democratic institutions. “With the exception of Pakistan, most of the Muslim countries surveyed think highly of democracy: In Albania, Egypt, Bangladesh, Azerbaijan, Indonesia, Morocco, and Turkey, 92 to 99 percent of the public endorsed democratic institutions—a higher proportion than in the United States (89 percent).”137 Rather, the most extreme differences in attitudes that they found concerned the role and place of women in society:
Huntington is mistaken in assuming that the core clash between the West and Islam is over political values. At this point in history, societies throughout the world (Muslim and Judeo-Christian alike) see democracy as the best form of government. Instead, the real fault line between the West and Islam, which Huntington’s theory completely overlooks, concerns gender equality and sexual liberalization. In other words, the values separating the two cultures have much more to do with eros than demos.138
What Norris and Inglehart mean by eros is what we have referred to as the first political order, or the sexual political order. Although Norris and Ingelhart focus on “the West and Islam,” the issue is much more complex than such a binary comparison would indicate. Instead, we argue that their survey results reveal evidence that the Syndrome runs much deeper than political preferences; it is a deep structural element of every society. The world may be becoming more homogenized with regard to certain attitudes, such as attitudes toward democracy, but it is definitely not homogenized with regard to choices about the first political order.
An excellent indicator of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome’s sexual political order is in the structural control offered men by family law systems.139 As Weiner expresses it, “the role of women in clan societies is to physically reproduce the clan itself, and this role shapes all the legal rules affecting them, from their ability to sue or be sued to their property rights.”140
Family law refers to the statutory and customary law that regulates marriage and parenthood, and to a great extent, it speaks to how a given state or society views the relations between men and women and subsequently, the families that form from their union. It establishes the legal order that defines how individuals and kin-based groups, whether families or tribes, relate to each other and the rights they hold as part of a family under the state. A state’s legal authority establishes practices that reproduce and govern family entities, but it is also true that social, community, and religious practices set up norms that govern family relations as well. A back-and-forth relationship exists between these two sources: although norms influence laws, laws also indisputably have an impact on norms.
According to our theoretical framework, the male-bonded kin group made family law in the image of its own patrilineal/fraternal interests. Consider the remarkable convergence of family law throughout both time and space in human history: adultery considered a much greater crime for women than for men; female infanticide as a historically sanctioned practice in virtually all human cultures, polygyny being legal but non-fraternal polyandry proscribed; divorce being easy for men and nearly impossible for women; male-on-female domestic violence and marital rape not recognized as crimes; a common legal sequel to rape being the marriage of the victim to the rapist; the legal age of consent and of marriage being years younger for women than for men; and inheritance of resources preferentially allocated to males. Still other practices that are an expression of physical and sexual dominance of men over women, such as infibulation, chastity belts, droit de seigneur, and gender-based dress codes that inhibit the mobility of women, are also understandable in this light.
The convergence in family law systems, expansively defined, through time and space, leads us to the conclusion that the formation of family law is at least in part the result of highly ranked men in all cultures having originally created family law through their political power and having created it in the image of male reproductive interests situated in the patrilineal/fraternal framework.141 Lerner points out that this explicit inequity in family law is apparent even in the earliest recorded legal system, the Code of Hammurabi.142 Consider Lerner’s observation that in ancient Sumerian, “the word ‘marriage’ is different for man and woman. A man ‘takes a wife,’ but a woman is described as ‘entering a man’s house.’ ”143 Even today, as the writer Al Lily notes, in Saudi Arabia, “wedding invitations display only the groom’s name and the name of the bride’s father.”144 Control over women by men, baldly put, is at the foundation of historical family law because of humanity’s common reliance on the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome as a security provision mechanism.145 Political scientists Mala Htun and Laurel Weldon express it well:
Family law—also called personal status law—is one of the central institutions of gender. It molds social identities and distributes rights and responsibilities, forging relations of power between men and women, parents and children, brothers and sisters. These status differences are consequential not just for the private sphere but also for public opportunities. Family laws shape the capacity of a citizen to own, inherit, and manage property; to work outside the home; her freedom to marry, divorce, and remarry; and her or his relationship with children. Most modern family law emphasizes patriarchy and other forms of male dominance. It tended (and still tends) to maximize men’s power over women and limit the latter’s ability to make decisions and take independent action. Classical Islamic law, the Napoleonic Code, Anglo‐American common law, and the customary law of many sub‐Saharan African groups and indigenous peoples of the Americas all upheld the notion that men were in charge of family life: they controlled property, were the legal guardians of children, and had the right to restrict their wives’ public activities. Women were obliged to obey their husbands, had limited access to divorce, and, in many traditions, fewer inheritance rights than men.146
It is possible even today to find full structural control in the patriline’s interest, as shown by the map in figure 3.10; however, some countries have made sustained and consistent departures from inequitable family and personal status law. For example, in many societies, it is as straightforward for a woman to obtain a divorce or to inherit from her parents as it is for a man. As Inglehart and Norris have argued (from survey results), so we argue (from our theoretical framework), that the key cultural differences between human societies may have less to do with ethnic and religious differences, and more to do with whether the society has chosen to continue with the patrilineal/fraternal security provision mechanism, or whether the society purposefully acts to mitigate that heritage. Family and personal status law offers a particularly insightful view of which path a society has taken to this point. As seen in chapter 1 and 2, overt physical dominance by males is typically buttressed by the creation of structural means to more easily ensure male control over females and thus over families. We should expect that inequitable family law systems and high levels of violence against women would be highly correlated, and indeed, that is exactly what we find.147
FIGURE 3.10 Map of Inequity in Family Law/Practice Favoring Men, scaled 2016
Remember that judicial structures—whether formal or informal—are typically male dominated. In more developed countries, judges and police are still primarily male; in less developed countries where village elders and councils informally adjudicate cases, these bodies are also usually exclusively male. For example, in India, village councils have doled out misogynist rulings time after time, prompting the Supreme Court of India to declare these councils should be illegal. For example, the Washington Post reports,
In 2014…a clan council in the state of West Bengal ordered the gang rape of a woman as punishment for her relationship with a man outside her tribal community—with a leader allegedly urging the council to “go enjoy the girl and have fun,” according to a police complaint…Women are forced to retrieve a coin from a vat of boiling oil to prove their purity. One woman was forced to walk, scantily clad, through the forest while the panchayat members threw balls of dough straight off a fire at her back…Women typically receive the harshest punishments.148
Oftentimes, these informal judicial structures attempt to stop victims from accessing the formal state-run system. One leader of a clan council stated, “We say, ‘Let’s not go to the courts; let’s resolve it,’ ” he said. “We encourage them to go back to the police if a [complaint] has already been filed and say, ‘I was not in a right state of mind; I want to take back my statement.’ ”149
In addition, with respect to the status of women, customary law often trumps formal national law.150 Indeed, in most states, where family law practice diverges from state family law, we typically find that the state stands mute and does not intervene. This may even be codified; in certain African states, for example Zambia and Botswana, formal laws may contain a clause at the end that explicitly states that where tribal and customary practices clash with state law, practice will supersede law. In Ethiopia, the legal marriage age is eighteen, but it is not uncommon for parents to contract marriages for their much younger daughters, including girls as young as seven, and the state does little to nothing to interfere.151 In Utah, Texas, and Arizona, as well as in British Columbia in Canada, breakout polygynous religious factions marry girls at young ages. In response, Utah and Arizona set the legal marriage age at eighteen and require parental consent for girls ages sixteen to seventeen years old. In Utah, girls of fifteen years not only need parental consent but also consent from the Juvenile Court, which must rule whether the marriage is voluntary and in her best interest. Arizona requires a court order as well as parental consent for girls fifteen years or younger.152 Despite these laws, many girls are still married in private religious ceremonies at ages as young as twelve.153 Polygyny is illegal in the United States and Canada, but nonetheless is practiced widely enough in some states that observers would be forced to conclude that these states do not prioritize enforcing laws against polygamy.
In addition, parallel systems of family and personal status law may be indulged to keep the peace, but this choice also has political consequences. Suad Joseph, a scholar of gender and the Middle East, writes here about Lebanon, but she could also be writing about other states with multiple family law systems:
That there is no civil family law in Lebanon further throws the citizens back onto their religious/ethnic affiliation and their families. The state defers marriage, divorce, child custody, and inheritance to the courts of the eighteen legally recognized religious sects. The religious clerics tend not only to encourage intra-sectarian marriages, as much as possible, but to reinforce the patriarchal familial structure in general. Thus, the state and religious institutions both rely on and work to construct family systems to keep individuals within their family structures. Political familism has a religious cosponsor.154
With this perspective in mind, the news that Iraq is considering formal establishment of sectarian family law is troubling. A proposed bill would consult the appropriate religious jurors according to the husband’s faith.155 In Lebanon, a similar provision led to religion-shopping on the part of men looking for the best personal outcome for themselves.156 According to the Human Rights Watch, the gauntlet for women is daunting:
Evangelical, Sunni, and Maronite courts alike dismiss evidence of abuse; while in Shia and Sunni divorce, women must prove the abuse “exceeds her husband’s legal authority to discipline his wife.” Catholics will not annul a marriage for abuse. In April 2014 Lebanon passed a landmark Law on Protection of Women and Family Members from Domestic Violence—but it is undercut by an exemption for personal status law and does not include marital rape.157
And, of course, these family sectarian courts are staffed almost exclusively by male judges.
Furthermore, the case of “borrowed law” adds an additional layer of complexity in the legal arena. For example, at independence, the North African countries of Morocco (1956), Algeria (1962), and Tunisia (1956) had the option to follow the French model of codified law or to return to the traditional system of Muslim religious courts. Each country saw a necessity for reform, and sought political consensus that allowed them to codify family law with some reforms (specific to each country) while still reflecting their Muslim heritage. At the same time, France, their colonial power, had yet to reform the Napoleonic Code of 1804, which had established a civil law based on male-dominated families. The North African countries eliminated some of the worst abuses of traditional Islamic law in their codes at that point. But many other problems, resulting in part from the French legacy, remained, which progressive reforms sought to rectify over the coming decades.158 Htun and Weldon note that in an ironic twist, “Some customary laws in Africa granted women more rights to land than the colonial laws that replaced them…Often, colonial rule codified a more uniform and male‐dominated version of indigenous practice than the social orders and family forms previously existing.”159
Both India and Turkey instituted reforms that were influential as other Muslim countries began searching for models. Indian Muslim reformers tried to reform Muslim law to accord to some British standards of human rights resulting in the Muslim Marriage Act of 1939, which regulated family law for India’s Muslim population. Turkey, the former seat of the Muslim caliphate, discarded traditional Islamic law and enacted the 1926 Civil Code, modeled after the 1912 Swiss personal status code. Thus, when discussing family and personal status law, it is important to recognize several historical layers of accretion in the law codes of former colonies and other regimes striving to break with the past, which may make reform that much more difficult.160
The path of family law reform is filled with zigs and zags, even in the twenty-first century, as may be expected when an issue of identity is involved.161 For example, change may not always mean greater equity or safeguards for women, but rather the opposite. Following the demise of the Soviet Union, the bias of judges against women claimants when adjudicating divorce cases in Central Asian republics has become far more pronounced.162 Some of these republics have even attempted to reintroduce legalized polygyny.163
This tension between individual rights, as recognized under the Convention on the Elimination on All Forms of Discrimination Against Women (CEDAW) and international human rights law, versus rights of the family and the community, is at its most powerful in issues concerning women and decision-making power within the family unit. It is not only men who may oppose such reforms; women may oppose them as well. For example, the heralded reforms to the Moroccan mudawana or family law code were facilitated by organized political action on the part of tens of thousands of Moroccan women and their male allies, which resulted in substantive change. Changes included increased autonomy for women, assertion of the wife’s equal responsibility with the husband for maintenance of the family, and an increase in women’s rights (e.g., to contract their own marriages, and to place all divorces before a judge). Equally notable was the degree of opposition to the reforms, even among women. Quite a few middle- and lower-class women were reluctant to endorse these reforms: many feared change, and some resented them as an unknown quantity pushed by the West and possibly prejudicial to women’s well-being.164
Despite increasing international pressure to end legal discrimination against women, demands to be governed by religious or traditional systems of family law have instead increased in recent years. In several Western nations, religious minorities maintain that equal representation under the law is possible only if family law systems are recognized as part of the legal fabric of the country. These proposed enclaves would allow religious courts to rule on issues of family law and would also grant exceptions to rights recognized under each country’s legal system.
Historically speaking, the concept of a legal enclave permitting diverse family law systems to coexist with a unified criminal law is not new. Far-flung empires, even more recent ones such as the Ottoman Empire and the British Empire, permitted localized family law systems based on religion and ethnicity. Several countries today, such as India and Bangladesh, maintain such a legal pluralism with regard to family law, with several family law systems being accommodated within the context of a common criminal code.165 The advantages asserted for legal pluralism include respect for cultural and religious integrity, traditions, and practice, but also the diminishing of conflict among groups by segregating practice along community lines.166
Allowing cultural and religious identity to be preserved is a recognized human right: the United Nations in 1992 issued the “Declaration on the Rights of Persons Belonging to National or Ethnic, Religious and Linguistic Minorities” (A/RES/47/135), which in turn cited Article 27 of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, declaring that “States shall take measures to create favorable conditions to enable persons belonging to minorities to express their characteristics and to develop their culture, language, religion, traditions and customs,” but in the same breath continues, “except where specific practices are in violation of national law and contrary to international standards.”167 Minority communities, notably Muslims in Western countries, argue that secular countries are negating their religious and cultural traditions by rejecting the practice of their family law systems.168
The question of the universality of women’s human rights cannot be avoided in this discussion about legal enclaves, however. For example, a 2009 United Nations Economic and Social Council report notes:
Compatibility between certain individual rights, including freedom to practice a religion or faith or to observe rites, and women’s fundamental rights as universal rights poses a major problem. The problem stems from the fact that the right to engage in certain practices injurious to women’s health or their position before the law or their status in general is claimed by persons, communities or States pursuing those practices or perceiving them as a component of freedom of religion and as a religious duty by which they and their ancestors have been bound from time immemorial and which in their eyes appear unrelated to issues concerned with the universal protection of women’s rights. Universality of the rights of women as individuals thus draws us into a classic yet still topical debate, that of the universality of human rights, and women’s rights in particular, in the face of cultural diversity. The issue is a sensitive one since practices or norms that impair the status of women originate, from the standpoint of the discriminator, in what are regarded as deeply held beliefs and, on a practical level, in rules, regulations or values based on or imputed to religion.169
This legitimate concern for cultural and religious integrity poses a dilemma. In the West, universal application of law recognizes individuals as the fundamental unit of society with uniform legal rights and obligations. Other cultural and religious traditions, however, may recognize collectives as the basic unit, and these collectives generally privilege senior male members and create mechanisms of structural control of females by males.170 It is difficult to mesh these two different legal traditions. Furthermore, as religious studies scholar Katherine Young insightfully notes, “When a religion has a predominantly ethnic base, any threat to the family is also a fundamental threat to the religion.”171
Interestingly, evidence shows that Muslim women living outside of Muslim-majority countries may not in fact support religious law enclaves.172 Jytte Klausen, author of a study that documented support for application of Islamic law in European countries, states that women “were notably less supportive of legal pluralism and multicultural devolution of authority to Islamic scholars and imams than were the male leaders.”173 This did not mean that the women were not observant Muslims. Although the women overwhelmingly sought freedom to practice their religion, they opposed being governed by religious personal status law. Three-quarters of the women in Klausen’s study rejected the proposition that secular law should be changed to devolve authority to religious leaders in matters of personal law, as did half of the men. Klausen emphasizes that this rejection does not reflect levels of religiosity or women’s positions on other issues.174
Klausen relates an interview with a young British lawyer who stated emphatically her allegiance to shari‘a law. When told that even very religious Muslim women did not want imams and shari‘a councils to issue binding decisions on family law matters, the woman exclaimed, “But oh no…they are right. You cannot trust these matters to imams. That would be terrible for women. We must have professionals make those decisions.”175 The question of whether women from cultures with relatively inequitable family law systems would prefer to be governed by secular family law is an important and underdeveloped area of research, deserving of greater attention by scholars in several social science fields. Legal scholar Robin Fretwell Wilson has offered the formula that parallel systems could be countenanced if and only if government courts are legally obligated to refuse the ruling of religious courts in the event that women, specifically, would be worse off under the religious judgment than a government judgment, concluding, “Society has a stake in the outcome.”176
We believe Wilson is right: society does have a stake in the outcome, and this volume speaks to the point.177 The relationship between law and practice is complex, and positive change depends on navigating that complexity. Law cannot dictate practice and often stands impotent before it, but law is nevertheless generally regarded as being a strong normative factor and capable of modifying practice over time, and importantly, of establishing state and community ideals.
In this sense, despite the ingrained nature of practice, contestation over law is often a critical first step in changing practice, although this process is long and complicated. In Uganda, under the Divorce Act, grounds for seeking divorce differ for men and women. For example, a man may obtain a divorce by proving his wife guilty of adultery. A woman seeking to divorce an adulterous husband not only must prove adultery but also must show that the husband committed, rape, bigamy, desertion, or sodomy to obtain a divorce and apply for a divorce settlement. A 2004 court case ruled that grounds for divorce should apply equally to men and women. Although it will take time for the court judgment to be accepted, judges held that the roles of men and women had changed significantly during the past century and the law should reflect this reality.178
Nevertheless, family law is a critical hinge point in the transition from the reliance on the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome as the society’s security provision mechanism to relinquishing that reliance. Htun and Weldon rightly observe that “as the state strengthens and expands, it often—but not always—seeks to seize control over family law from churches, clans, tribes, and other cultural communities…. Transformative state projects seeking to secularize, modernize, and civilize the nation and the polity are often played out on the terrain of the family.”179 We return to this point in part III, in which we discuss the dynamics of change.
Property and Inheritance Rights of Women
Keeping resources within the patriline, as we have seen, requires both that inheritance and property rights favor men and that major economic resources such as land will remain solely within male hands and be passed from male to male within the patriline. Thus, women’s property rights in practice (as opposed to formal law) are strongly indicative of whether extended male kin networks play an important role in societal governance (see figure 3.11). As Fukuyama notes, “The ability of women to own and bequeath property is an indicator of the deterioration of tribal organization and suggests that strict patrilineality [has] disappeared.”180
FIGURE 3.11 Map of Property Rights in Law and Practice for Women, scaled 2017
In societies reliant on the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome as a security provision mechanism, brothers and husbands are the favored property holders, for they are the “true” members of the family, being the expression of the patriline.181 With regard to brothers, Goody aptly notes, “Inheritance and marriage rules are seen as intimately related, both being linked to the mutual claims of brother and sister.”182 We thus see in many societies that a woman may have a lesser right (or no right) to inherit from her parents so that her brothers may inherit all real property. Given that patrilocal marriage attends this Syndrome, it is sons who will presumably stay and take care of their elderly parents, entitling them and their male descendants to the assets of the patriline.
Goods given by the bride’s family at her wedding, or dowry (if that is the custom), are thus considered to be the inheritance of daughters, a type of premortem inheritance. Thus, even when women are given equal inheritance rights by formal law, they may feel they cannot exercise those rights because their brothers will be upset. Should the woman find herself divorced, it may well be these very brothers to whom she would have to turn for help. She cannot afford to anger them by asserting her inheritance rights, and so she will often sign over her land rights to her brothers.183
The situation is even more controversial with respect to husbands and their surviving widows. When a man dies, his agnatic kin may lay claim to all his goods, and in some cultures, this means that the widow, and possibly also her children, are left homeless and without any property at all. In other cultures, the children (especially sons) may be kept within the patriline, and only the wife is turned out. In yet other cultures, the dead man’s property includes not only all of the man’s material possessions, but also his children and even his wife. Women not only may not inherit from their husbands, but also may actually be inherited, usually by a brother of her dead husband, to whom she may owe wifely services, including childbearing.
Thus, a perfect storm can overtake a woman if she is widowed or divorced, given her lack of property rights. In a 2016 article, the Economist notes, “In several places custom dictates that only men can inherit land. In Uganda stories abound of widows being turfed off their marital land by in-laws. One woman was thrown out of her home a week after her husband died in an accident; she had refused to marry any of his five brothers, and her children were taken away to a sister-in-law.”184
Land is especially salient in every discussion of women’s property rights, and the thought that women could own land—one of the very foundations of the agnatic identity—would seem outrageous. Das Gupta’s observation about Asia holds in other regions, as well: “Patrilineages functioned as corporations. Although land was privately held, people could not sell land inherited from the patrilineage to an outsider, without giving members of the lineage the first right of refusal.”185 Women, notably, are always considered “outsiders” to the patriline.
Thus, it makes sense that, for example, women own only 13 percent of land in India, even though three-quarters of Indian women make their living as farmers.186 Estimates are that in the MENA region, only 4 percent of women have title to land.187 Reporter Tina Rosenberg explains,
The consequences are enormous. Without title, female farmers acting on their own don’t have access to credit, subsidies, government programs for seeds, irrigation or fertilizer. They cannot get loans and do not invest to improve their yields. They live in fear that someone more powerful—which is everyone—can kick them off their land. When women’s incomes suffer, so do their children. More than 40 percent of all children under 5 in India are malnourished. And India’s agricultural productivity is needlessly diminished. Landlessness also raises the risk of domestic violence.188
Indeed, research has shown that women who own land are up to eight times less likely to suffer domestic violence.189 Furthermore, lack of land rights is associated with higher rates of HIV among women, which is attributed to lower bargaining power within the household for women, hampering them in negotiating safe sex practices.190
The lack of property and land rights severely hampers women, not only with regard to household-level bargaining between men and women that in turn affects their children but also as economic actors. Lack of property and land rights cuts a woman off from credit, for she has no real collateral to offer. It may also reduce her ability to live independently, for she cannot sell or lease real property. She may not be able to control how the land is used, or how the proceeds from the use of the land are distributed. In many cultures, political participation may be linked to land rights, as may head-of-household status, which may confer additional rights.191
These issues are so sensitive that even where great progress has been made on reform of personal status laws, such as we see in Morocco (2004) and Tunisia (1956 and 2014), the issue of inheritance—especially inheritance of land or other male-coded goods such as cattle—is still off limits in terms of reform, even at the time of this writing.192
As alluded to earlier in this subsection, property rights are a pivotal stage in transition away from reliance on the patrilineal/fraternal security provision mechanism. Goody concludes, “We should view the formal rights of women to inherit equally with their brothers both movable and immovable properties as the critical transforming agent.”193 Goody is of the opinion that
The fact that women are heirs to significant property affects the whole nature of the conjugal relationship…leading it…. to be associated [with] the concept of “love.” Gluckman has argued that “love” serves to separate both spouses from their kin (and kin groups), uniting them in a conjugal team. Such separation is an aspect of love in the modern Western world; if you have to love one woman more than someone else (whether sibling, parent, or partner), then a rationale is established for splitting society into spatially distinct groups based upon monogamous unions.194
In other words, women’s property and land rights give rise to neolocal marriage, rather than patrilocal marriage, and neolocal marriage is also more resistant to polygyny.195 In other words, several of the magnetic beads of the Syndrome begin to unlink when women’s property rights are established.
Three Indicators of Violence Against Women, and Sanction of Such Violence
Human sexual dimorphism enabling most men to physically coerce most women (as noted in chapter 1), including the ability to impregnate them against their will through rape, is arguably at the heart of the first political order. If coercion and rape of women are given sanction, or at least impunity, within the collective, that choice will reverberate through every societal practice and institution. Indeed, virtually all of the components of the Syndrome, whether lack of property rights for women, son preference, or polygyny, are merely logical extensions of this foundational coercive choice.
Criminologist and gender scholar Hilde Jakobsen rightly proposes that “violence [must be] integrated into social theory in ways that recognize its significance both in maintaining social order and in the very constitution of the social…Violence constitutes social order, making and reproducing structures of inequality, [aided by] discourses that authorize violence.”196 “Consent,” then, may be a façade behind which coercion hides. In her fieldwork in Tanzania, this was openly explained to Jakobsen as she asked questions about wife-beating.
More specifically, Jakobsen realized the norm underpinning the behavior was that “men should govern, and if they governed rationally, they could legitimately use violence to govern.”197 Her focus groups revealed that “A strategically administered beating could make a wife more governable…Steering a wife’s choices, then, was a beating’s legitimizing goal.”198 Indeed, the focus groups she worked with found it “hilarious or perverse” that a wife could beat her husband for his mistakes and faults, and so “women cannot beat men with the approval with which men can beat women…It was husbands, not wives, who should control their spouse by violence if necessary, and it was wives, not husbands, who should submit to this coercive control.”199 Why? The answer was really very simple: “to beat was to censure through violence, and that who censured whom was a question of who ruled whom. The good beating, then, is violence that orders society: supported by a dominant discourse insofar as it enforced a specific power order between husband and wife…the perceived social legitimacy of violence is what makes it powerful.”200 With coercion so near the surface, women develop strategies of self-defense that look like acquiescence: “Women’s self-censorship is for self-protection…Women themselves enforce the norm so that men will not use violence to enforce it. This shows that it is not with full and free consent that women support the norms.”201
Have any societies not made such a coercive choice in its first sexual political order? Peggy Reeves Sanday asserts there have been diarchic societies in which men and women rule together.202 Usually, a system of checks and balances is in place, such as in societies where women own the land, appoint the male chiefs, and then retain veto power over his decisions. At the household level, men and women share responsibilities and actively cooperate. Men do not segregate themselves into a fraternal order, and sex is not a commodity. Interestingly, in these societies, Sanday asserts the concept of “gang rape” is unheard of.
Even Sanday admits, however, that such diarchic societies have been rare. Rather, what we see today are many societies in which the components of the Syndrome are still pretty much in place to one degree or another, and a few other societies where those components have been largely dismantled. Even in those latter cultures, however, the key reservoir allowing for possible resurgence of the Syndrome lies in the ubiquity of women’s physical insecurity. For example, in a phenomenon dubbed the “Nordic Paradox,” researchers have observed that Scandinavian countries have a disproportionately high level of intimate partner violence (IPV) compared with the rest of Europe. This is unexpected, for Scandinavian women have gained unprecedented levels of gender equality within their societies.203 Whether this higher level of IPV stems from a backlash or simply higher reporting rates is unclear.
What is clear, however, is that within virtually all societies, it seems, women’s everyday physical insecurity is viewed as completely unremarkable, and in this way, given tacit sanction. Levels of domestic violence, rape, and even domestic murder remain high, even in states that have largely done away with other components of the Syndrome.204 Phumzile Mlambo-Ngcuka, executive director of UNWomen, has stated that “Violence is the biggest challenge facing women around the world,” with “even countries that have the highest indicators on gender equality like Iceland, they still have to confront the issue of violence against women.”205
In states encoding components of the Syndrome, violence may be endemic. Development scholar Deepa Narayan says of her nation, “India can arguably be accused of the largest-scale human rights violation on Earth: the persistent degradation of the vast majority of its 650 million girls and women.” She explains:
In 2016, the rape of minor girls increased by 82 percent compared with the previous year. Chillingly, across all rape cases, 95 percent of rapists were not strangers, but family, friends, and neighbors…Indian government surveys show that 42 percent of girls in the country have been sexually abused…Over 50 percent of Indian men and women still believe that sometimes women deserve a beating. One woman is killed every hour for not bringing in enough dowry to a husband.206
In South Africa, legal scholar Shima Baradaran found that South Africa is rightly called the rape capital of the world, with a woman raped every twenty-six seconds, and one in three South African women being raped in their lifetime. The norm of violence against women is ingrained in even the youngest in the society. Baradaran tells of a grandmother from the Eastern Cape who recounted that one evening her three-year-old grandson told her, “you better not take your panties off, grandma or I’ll rape you in the night.”207 Her informants told her that rape was a form of compensation used by men who felt their status was threatened and thus must be reasserted in a dramatic fashion. Women were perceived as acceptable objects against which violence could be used, and rape was perceived as an act speaking directly to the perpetrator’s masculinity.
Masculinity and violence against women was intertwined even when rape was not present; Baradaran found her Xhosa informants joked that “Xhosa men always keep a stick under their pillow, for their wife.”208 Interestingly, Baradaran felt that brideprice played a role in this view of women as objects who could be beaten or used sexually at will: “The Xhosa man pays lobola [and] the traditional view of women as property implies that a man may use any means to control his wife as he would his other property.”209 Bride raiding was also traditionally practiced in this culture, and the infidelity of men and lack of emotional attachment to women is highly praised. One convicted rapist summed up his mind-set, “I knew I was hurting her. It gave me power. I was in control.”210
In our scaling of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome, we look specifically at three indicators to gain purchase on the level of control-by-coercion of women present in the society: (1) overall prevalence of violence against women, and then two measures of societal attitudes toward such violence, including (2) the existence of widespread sanction or impunity for those harming women under certain circumstances (e.g., honor killings, accusations of witchcraft), as well as (3) the construction of rape as a property crime perpetrated not primarily against a woman but against her male kin. That is, rather than the law recognizing the woman has been physically assaulted, the more important question appears to be restitution of honor to the woman’s male kin. Under such a conceptualization, the law will often provide that a rapist may be exonerated if he offers to marry his victim, thus making good the property crime against the victim’s male kin—but making the victim’s life a double tragedy. The maps for each of these three indicators are presented in figures 3.12, 3.13, and 3.14.
FIGURE 3.12 Map of the Overall Physical Security of Women, scaled 2014
FIGURE 3.13 Map of the Societal Sanction/Impunity for the Murder of Women/Femicide, scaled 2016
FIGURE 3.14 Map of Legal Exemption for Rapists if Marriage Proposed, scaled 2015
Most important, male fraternity—the end goal of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome—depends on defining and then subjugating those who are other-than-men, that is, women. Sanday comments on how “abuse of women [is] a means to renew fraternal bonds and assert power as a brotherhood…the unstated goal is agreement and fraternal unity.”211 Because the “otherness” is based on sex, sexual aggression—particularly gang rape—becomes the ultimate symbolic display of male dominance. Sanday goes so far as to assert, “I suggest that rape is not an integral part of male nature, but the means by which men programmed for violence and control use sexual aggression to display masculinity and to induct men into masculine roles.”212 As a consequence, love and compassion are reserved for brothers only. Even the “bro talk” about “tits and asses” that accompanies Wall Street financial circles shows how “the bonding…goes hand in hand with the objectification of the other sex.”213
Although men may have depended on women when they were children, they now feel liberated from that dependence on their mothers by becoming dependent solely on the fraternal bond. That bond demands men earn the respect of other men through the repudiation and the subordination of anything female. After all, “Without the fraternity there is no power—there is certainly no power that accrues to the individual male.”214 Dominance carries with it not only a feeling of potency, then, but also a sense of security, while those who are dominated feel fear and depression.215 Furthermore, even in the context of a male dominance hierarchy in which nonelite males may experience domination, they can always recapture those heady feelings by dominating those who are not part of the fraternity—women, in the first place, but also out-groups. As sociologist Theodore Kemper expresses it, “the dominant are not dependent for their sense of well-being on the voluntary responses of others. The dominant simply take what they want.”216
That this learned behavior cascades outward can be seen in the interviews Sanday conducted with fraternity members in the United States; one instructive quote from just such a young man states, “The belief that ‘no means yes’ is not necessarily just a notion of convenience to allow us to push for gratification. It is part of the general cycle of abuse and ignoring the needs of others by which we learn to pursue all of our social and sexual goals with other people.”217 Truly, the bootcamp for autocracy is often the relationship between the sexes, or as political scientist Ariel Ahram observes, “Modes of gender domination offer models for domination and marginalization of other groups.”218
Coercion for the sake of asserting masculinity is a prominent motivation for violence at the level of individual males, but it is also true that the logic holds at the kin group level, as well. The interests of the male kin group must dominate over female interests, but patrilines often find that women—even women born to the patriline—often do not share their interests. Mothers may object to child marriages of their daughters. Sisters may object to a lack of inheritance. Wives may object to male dominance in household decision making, including decisions that bring a new wife into the family. Therefore, in addition to inequities in family law that keep male interests superordinate—such as arranged child marriage, polygyny, and patrilocality—the patriline is also prepared to use physical force to enforce the dominance of its interests over those of women. Thus, we expect that societies reliant on the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome as a security provision mechanism would tolerate the highest levels of violence against women (even though all societies tolerate a significant level of such violence).219 That is why even when new laws against violence against women are proposed, such as in Morocco, spousal abuse is often excepted, for the woman is the property, if you will, of the patriline.220
To uphold the patriline’s interests in cases where childhood socialization is not effective, more coercive means will be unveiled. In Rizvi and colleagues’ study, they conducted thirty focus group interviews with 250 women in Pakistan, a country with a high Syndrome score. They found that
from childhood, girls are informed, taught and trained to believe that only men who are physically powerful and hence mentally competent to make decisions; “She is counseled, and if this does not work, she is forced through threats and violence to believe that she is an object that has to be operated by a male family member” [emphasis added]. In cases where women challenge these patriarchal privileges and/or seek to enforce their rights, violence is used as a means to control them.221
Moreover, they explain that the types of violence the women in their study were quite varied: “It could be physical ranging from slapping to burning; verbal such as taunting, use of bad language; mental like threats of divorce and actual divorce; and sexual in the form of rape and incest.”222
Violence against women in the home is endemic in our world. Note, however, that the levels of violence are the highest in those countries encoding more of the components of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome. The Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS) ask whether wife-beating is justified. Although data are missing for many countries, the following is a sample of countries with the highest percentages reported among men, with the Syndrome score of the country noted in parentheses (table 3.1).
TABLE 3.1 Percent of Men Who Feel Wife-Beating Is Justified
Country (Syndrome Score) |
Percent of Men Who Feel Wife-Beating Is Justified (%) |
Afghanistan (15) |
72 |
Albania (9) |
36 |
Azerbaijan (8) |
58 |
Bangladesh (14) |
36 |
Burundi (10) |
44 |
Chad (14) |
51 |
Congo (11) |
40 |
Cote d’Ivoire (13) |
42 |
Democratic Republic of Congo (11) |
61 |
Equatorial Guinea (12) |
52 |
Eritrea (12) |
45 |
Gabon (13) |
40 |
Guinea (13) |
66 |
India (14) |
42 |
Kyrgyzstan (9) |
50 |
Laos (8) |
49 |
Lesotho (14) |
40 |
Madagascar (9) |
46 |
Mali (14) |
51 |
Myanmar (7) |
49 |
Pakistan (14) |
32 |
Solomon Islands (13) |
57 |
Timor-Leste (12) |
81 |
Uganda (12) |
44 |
Tanzania (14) |
40 |
Uzbekistan (8) |
61 |
Vanuatu (10) |
60 |
Source: UNICEF (updated 2017).
These are fairly alarming percentages, and it comes as no surprise that these countries also encode for many other components of the Syndrome, as indicated by their scores on that scale. The wide variety of forms of violence against women is also staggering—from estimates that one woman is killed every hour in India because of insufficient dowry,223 to estimates that up to two hundred women are killed each year as witches in Papua New Guinea224 (a country where 41 percent of men admitted to having raped a woman who was not their partner, and 13 percent of rapes are committed against girls under the age of seven years old).225
It comes as no surprise, then, that societal sanction is often given to the harming or even killing of women, providing impunity for such crimes.226 Reasons of male honor are often invoked, and these crimes may have deep cultural resonance. As Al Lily explains about Saudi Arabia, “masculinity is measured not mainly according to how muscular and tough a man is, but also according to how jealous and protective he is of his female relatives. The masculinity of a man is questioned if a female relative of his has done anything immoral or culturally inappropriate. His masculinity comes into question if anything bad happens to her, and he could not protect her.”227 In Ecuador, the saying goes, “A man’s honor lies between the legs of a woman.”228
Even in more developed countries, there may be subcultures where male honor is inextricably tied up with female sexual behavior. In Texas (appeal decided 2002), a man was given a four months’ sentence for killing his ex-wife due to “sudden passion,” while given fifteen years for wounding her lover at the very same time.229 These crimes are so universal that special terms have been coined to denote them such as “femicide,” “honor killings,” or “honor suicides” (which are typically forced suicides, and therefore more rightly regarded as murders).
Sanction for a female’s killing may extend beyond a woman’s sexual behavior to any type of “deviant” woman. As we have seen, if one is regarded as a “witch,” one may be killed with impunity in certain cultures. Often perpetrators feel they are undertaking a heroic task. One of a mob who killed a “witch” in Papua New Guinea was quoted as saying, “I see myself as a guardian angel. We feel that we kill on good grounds and we’re working for the good of the people in the village.”230
This idea that the femicide is a virtuous act is common. The brother who kills to cleanse the family honor after his sister has been raped may say, “Yes, she’s my sister and I love her, but it is a duty.”231 When this degree of societal sanction for femicide exists, it is clear the interests of the patriline and the fraternity are paramount.
Even when laws exist to protect women from violence, as they do in almost all modern states, they may seldom be enforced. For example, the State Department’s human rights report on Rwanda for 2007 notes that in police stations, the government did not feed detainees awaiting hearings or transfers. Police regularly told victims of violence and rape, especially women, that if they did not provide food to their attacker, they would release him.232 To make matters worse, a woman often would face sexual assault at the hands of the police when she delivered the food required to keep her rapist in jail.
Another example comes from Algeria. In 2015, all cheered when Algeria passed a new law against domestic violence, providing for up to twenty years’ detention for those found guilty of injuring one’s spouse, and up to life in prison if the violence resulted in death. The legislation, however, included a clause that the woman could legally “pardon” her attacker, and if she did, he would not be prosecuted.233 The pressure on the woman to pardon her husband would be immense under such circumstances, thus, in a sense, making the law null and void. Worldwide, according to the World Health Organization, about 40 percent of all murders of women are committed by intimate partners.234
Our third and final indicator examines whether a rapist can be exonerated if he offers to marry his victim. When rape is considered a property crime against a patriline, and not a crime against a woman, the society is again foregrounding the interests of the patriline and the fraternity over and against the interests of women. As Yuval Harari observes, “In many societies women were simply the property of men, most often their fathers, husbands or brothers. Rape, in many legal systems, falls under property violation—in other words, the victim is not the women who was raped but the male who owns her.”235 This is linked to the fact that the woman’s body is perceived not to belong to her, but to the group. Jacobson suggests, “Virginity reflects a commitment—perhaps a forced commitment—to the community…Virginity represents sacrifice of self and body to the larger good, a spiritual virtue, a commitment to social institutions from family to the community.”236
More specifically, in 2015, 51 countries had laws that exonerate rapists if they offer to marry their victim, usually accompanied by a payment of cash or assets to the father’s family.237 The double trauma caused to such women—rape, then forced to marry your rapist—may be enough to induce suicide. In fact, Morocco changed its law on rape exoneration because of the suicide of Amina Filali, who was only sixteen years old when she swallowed rat poison to escape being married to her rapist.238 Tunisia and Jordan have followed suit, but as of this writing, such laws were still on the books in countries such as Lebanon, the Philippines, Tajikistan, and several other countries as our map shows.239 Furthermore, it may be that conceptualizing it as a property crime against men catalyzes rape as a form of plunder during wartime.240
All in all, then, any examination of the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome must give an account of the coercion that undergirds its first political order. From that fountainhead of violence come not only the components of the Syndrome but also a cascade of negative effects that sap the stability, resilience, and security of the society.
Concluding Thoughts
We have traversed an immense amount of ground in this chapter. In great detail, we have examined the logic of each subordinative mechanism in the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome, noted its current prevalence worldwide, and assessed its negative effects on the lives of women and girls. We have illuminated how these mechanisms interlock, forming a tightly woven straitjacket constraining women. We noted that this straitjacket can exist even in the presence of high female literacy and with high female labor force participation as well as in the context of relatively high levels of representation of women in the national legislature. We have trained our eyes to see these Syndrome mechanisms at work much closer to home.
It is now time to assess whether the Patrilineal/Fraternal Syndrome not only constrains and harms women, but also constrains and harms the larger society. We argue that what is done to women, ultimately is done to the nation-state. If women are subject to autocracy in their homes, so will the society be subject. If women are terrorized in their homes, so will the society be challenged by terrorism. If women are exploited by corruption in their homes, so will the society be plagued with exploitation and corruption.
In part II, we take an inventory of those negative effects for the larger society of the choice to subordinate women. We first lay out a theoretical framework from which we derive testable empirical propositions linking the presence of the Syndrome to a wide-ranging set of negative outcomes on dimensions of national security and stability. We end part II with a comprehensive empirical investigation of these propositions.