IN the Vth and IVth centuries industry in Greece assumed an economic and social importance which did not escape attention. When Socrates would indicate the composition of the Athenian Assembly, before mentioning the husbandmen and the small tradesmen he enumerates the fullers, the shoemakers, the masons, and the metal-workers. The men of the crafts can form the majority; their chiefs become the masters of the commonwealth. Demos gives himself into the hands of lamp-merchants, turners, leather-dressers, and cobblers, and Aristophanes puts this statement into the mouth of a sausage-seller. Moreover, the citizens abandon the lower kinds of work, and in the accounts of public works they appear as an aristocracy of labour, lost in the multitude of Metics and slaves. Nor was Athens an exception. The little towns of the Peloponnese swarmed with craftsmen; their military contingents were almost entirely formed of men with professions. The industrial callings even attracted women. Many freedwomen and daughters of citizens reduced to need devoted themselves to the works of Athene Ergane. They wove for custom, they sold yarn, ribbons, clothes, and bonnets of their own making, or they plaited wreaths.
But, if a great part of the population lived by industry, it does not follow that it was industry on a large scale. First, we must not be misled by the concentration of many workshops in the same city or in the same quarter. We involuntarily think of the great manufacturing towns of modern times when we see the Cerameicos in Athens entirely occupied by the potters, the tanneries collected outside the city, the Peirseeus filled with workshops which manufacture imported raw materials and work for export, and Laureion inhabited by a whole people of miners and metal-workers. In order not to misinterpret this concentration, it is sufficient to recall analogous facts. There are also in Athens a Street of the Box-Merchants and a Street of the Herm-Sellers, and the craftsmen teem round the Agora. The workshops are innumerable. Some are big enough to be called factories, but none is a huge concern of the modern kind. Rival manufacturers live next door to each other; they are jealous of each other, but the struggle is not bitter, for there is work for all and the weak are not crushed by the strong. Small
FIG. 38. SPINNING-WOMAN DRAWING OUT HER YARN. CUP FROM ORVIETO. (D.A., Fig. 3382.)
industry predominates; medium-sized industry plays a certain part; large industry barely makes a vague appearance.
The first cause which prevented one whole class of industries from developing indefinitely was the persistence of work in the home. At the time when the miller Nausicydes and the baker Cyrebos were each amassing a great fortune, housewives were still employed, like their grandmothers, in pounding the corn and kneading the dough. They kept the manufacture of clothing in their hands from the moment when the fleece was brought to them to the moment when they gave their menfolk the finished chiton. The greatest ladies of Greece taught their daughters everything connected with the making of clothes. Like the wise Arete, Queen of the Phseacians, the mother of the tyrant Jason span and wove in her palace. Everywhere the mistress of the gynaeceum
FIG. 39. THE WEAVING-LOOM. BOEOTIAN VASE OF THE VTH CENTURY. (D.A., Fig. 6845.)
held, in Plato’s words, “the government of shuttles and distaffs.” Indeed it was in these home work-rooms that an industry which worked for the public was born. For that
FIG. 40. THE WEB OF PENELOPE. VASE FROM CHIUSI. (D.A., Fig. 6844).
it was sufficient that the output should exceed the requirements of the house and that the surplus should be sold. This might happen without fixed intention, but it was also done with the deliberate purpose of practising a profession. In this way Athens manufactured men’s clothing; Megara specialized in the worker’s exomis; Corinth put on the markets its blankets, its kalasireis of fine wool, and its linen cloth; Pellene made cloaks which were in great demand; Patrse was filled with women, thanks to its byssos weaving-works; Cos had a name for its bombyx silk goods; Chios, Miletos, and Cyprus sent their hangings, their embroidered garments, and their carpets far and wide; Taras grew rich on its linen stuffs; and Syracuse transformed the wool of Sicily into textiles of many colours. But the textile industry, even when it had become a special profession, produced in small quantities. For common materials, the families only turned to it for a supplement to their own output, and preferred to call in women by the day. For the finer qualities manufacture was scattered and the demand limited.
Even those industries which were entirely in the service of the public kept some traces of the family system. The son fairly often succeeded his father. In the liberal careers the case was very frequent; the schools of medicine and music were family groups, the history of sculpture and painting is that of a few houses, and the architects of Delphi were, in succession, two Agathons, then Agasicrates, the son of the second, and lastly Agathocles, the son or brother of Agasicrates. In the same way the industrial art of the potters was handed down in the family. “How long,” says Plato, “the potter’s son helps his father and watches him at work before he touches the wheel himself!” In the other industries we find similar examples, but they are far fewer. Cleon inherited a tannery from his father, Anytos left one to his son, Lysias and his brother Polemarchos began by manufacturing shields like their father Cephalos, Athenogenes made perfumes like his father and grandfather before him, and among the contractors at Eleusis we see Antimachos son of Neocleides succeeded by Neocleides son of Antimachos. But each chose his own profession freely, and we see manufacturers’ sons eager to escape from the paternal mill and to plunge into politics. The exodus of men from the country contributed to the recruiting of the industrial class, while the sons of craftsmen became artists, doctors, and orators. Individuals went from one profession to another with extreme mobility. Hereditary professions were not the rule.
In any case there was nothing like the great factory with countless hands. The largest establishment of which we know in Attica was the shield factory which the Syracusan Cephalos founded in the Peiraeeus in 435 and handed down to his sons. In 404 it contained 120 slaves. After that come the two houses managed by the father of Demosthenes. For the people of the time these “were neither of them small industries.” Now the arms factory had 32 or 33 slaves, the bed factory 20. A shield factory bequeathed to Apollodoros did, it is true, produce twice the output of the armoury bequeathed to Demosthenes, and therefore may have contained twice the personnel. Even then we have only one industry which employed more than a hundred workers, and those which employed more than twenty were considered very large. The celebrated potter Duris probably had not more than a dozen men about him. The gang of shoe-makers inherited by Timarchos consisted of nine or ten slaves, and in a mime of Herondas the fashionable shoe-maker has thirteen. The mines, it is true, present a very different aspect; there slaves were hired by the hundred. But when a man needed a big staff of working miners it was because he had obtained by auction a large number of small concessions. The State only gave out small lots. The typical mine employed about thirty men underground, about the same in the washing-room, and far less in the foundry. We know of one concessionnaire who put his hand to the pick and had for total capital a sum of 4,500 drachmas; with such initial assets he cannot have had more than fifteen or twenty workers under him.
Athenian industry, then, never involved a great agglomeration of workers in one undertaking. What is typical of this industry is not the factory in which Cephalos collected over a hundred hands, but rather the hovel in which the Micylos of the poet Crates cards wool with his wife “to escape starvation,” or the workshop in which, according to an inscription, the helmet-maker Dionysios worked together with his wife, the gilder Atremis. And these are not accidental, isolated cases. The Athenian craftsman had no interest in increasing the number of his workers, Xenophon says. He was in the same position as the farmer, who knew exactly how many day-workers he needed, and that one man above this number was a sheer loss.
Whether they were conducted by the family or by a single owner, these workshops with their small personnel did not require much capital. As a rule, big fortunes, even in a city like Athens, were rare, and, being exposed to the risks inseparable from investments at high rates of interest, they were ephemeral. But industry did not attract them especially, and it did without them. A small foundry was worth 1,700 drachmas, including slaves. Even the mines could keep going without a great concentration of capital; one concession of the normal type with thirty slaves served as security for a loan of 10,500 drachmas, and another for a mortgage of one talent; and a man with 4,500 drachmas bid at the auction. It might be supposed that ship-building at least would have required huge yards and the formation of big companies. It had to supply a merchant fleet which covered the whole Mediterranean and a war navy which had 300 vessels in the Vth century and over 400 in the IVth. But what do we see in reality? One hundred and eighty-three ships, the builders of which are known to us, were launched in fifty-two years from fifty-nine different yards. It was the same with the public works contractor. With the system of giving orders in small lots and paying by instalments in advance, he did not need to have much money. When craftsmen united for big jobs it was the labour of their little firms that they were combining. Even those factories which prospered do not seem to have been capable of enlargement by the increase of capital. The banker Pasion would have had no difficulty from the financial point of view in extending the factory which was already bringing him a talent a year; yet he did nothing of the kind. Demosthenes’ father obtained an income of only 30 minas from his armoury; in his bed factory he sank only a capital of 40 minas and a floating capital of 150 minas; apparently he did not see his way to developing these two concerns, since they did not prevent him from buying a house for 30 minas and drawing 177 minas interest a year on loans and deposits. Timarchos did not increase his staff of nine or ten shoemakers; he preferred to acquire a weaving-woman and an embroiderer, and invested in land. Conon had a bonnet-weaving establishment and a drug business, without either workshop suffering from the existence of the other. In the Peiræeus we find a workshop with dwelling-quarters rented for 54 drachmas; nowhere do we find a great factory representing a fortune.
For the soul of the great factory is the machine; and without machinery the great manufacturer does not supersede the craftsman. The slaves were quite enough for the output; there was no need to rack one’s brains to cope with shortage or dearness of labour. The Greek engineers distinguished between simple machines and composite machines. The former were five in number, the lever, the wedge, the
FIG. 41.
HOIST, BEFORE SETTING UP. (D.A., Fig. 4745.)
a, wooden legs; b, fore-stays; c, back-stays; d, upper block; e, gear-rope; f, lower block, fastened to a pile; g, windlass.
screw, the windlass, and the pulley or block. The latter were merely combinations of the former, and the only one known in the Vth century was the crane. Archytas was the first to apply geometry to mechanics; he caused perceptible progress to be made in the theory and practice of the lever, and solved several problems of traction, to the advantage of construction and shipping. But no advance was made beyond the apparatus invented by the architects Chersiphron and Metagenes for the land transport of heavy material. Loads were lifted with the help of two-legged machines or sheers. These were erected in yards and on harbour moles. In the mines the shortness of leases and the cheapness of labour retarded technical progress. Since the only object was the immediate return, and no one troubled about making extraction easier for future concessionaires, the section of the galleries was small, no winding plant was installed at the pit-heads, and mechanical crushing was unknown; all the work was done by strength of arm. The smelting and refining furnaces, though not expensive, were fairly developed, but they did not make it possible to separate gold from silver. The bronze-workers obtained wonderful colour-effects, but this metal polychromy was attained by the simplest methods, incrustation, the juxtaposition of different alloys, gilding, silver-plating, or patient, skilful patination. By Callias’ process certain dye-stuffs were extracted from argentiferous lead, in particular cinnabar or vermilion, but always without any expensive plant. The same is probably true of the process invented by a woman of Cos for winding silk-cocoons. The vase paintings often represent workshops with a few implements hung on the walls. (See Figs. 44-46.) It is Greek industry that we see here, with its apparatus of primitive simplicity and its low output.
It made no great demands in respect of raw material, either. This was often supplied to the craftsman by his customer. The family which could not weave enough cloth for itself gave yarn to a workwoman, who wove it in the house or at her own home. In a play of Aristophanes a goldsmith and a harness-maker go to a house to mend a clasp and a strap. When he wanted some building done, Timotheos procured timber from Macedonia. When the State undertook public works, it divided them up into lots and chose in each case between two systems, either doing the work itself or giving it to a private contractor. The latter method had the advantage of laying all the responsibility on one or more contractors. The former was necessary for difficult work which required artistic perfection or, where the task could not be divided up, a comparatively large quantity of personnel, materials, and capital. For the work which it did itself the State supplied everything. It bought the gold and ivory from which Pheidias was to make the statue of the Goddess. For other statues it procured copper and tin, fuel for the casting, and the beams and planks of the inclined plane and the platform. If column-drums had to be brought to the site, it made a road, built waggons, and only asked the transport agents for beasts at so much a day. It would instal a windlass at its own cost and give the iron-work out on contract; it procured tools for the workmen and had them steeled when they became worn. It was to relieve itself of these cares that the State turned more and more to the contractor. Yet it still supplied him with scaffolding, stone, wood, lead, iron, and bronze. When an administrative body decided to adorn a temple with a monumental entrance, it began by acquiring cedar or cypress, ivory, glue, and pins. If the contractor must himself supply the materials or engines needed, if the mason was to furnish common stone for the foundations, or if the carpenter was to bring his own scaffolding, this condition had to be expressly stipulated. The ordinary rule was that the craftsman sold his labour and nothing else.
All these advantages did not, however, draw a very large number of contractors, especially of such as had considerable means at their disposal. The State tried all manner of devices to divide up the lots and to organize competition; orders were brought within the power of the humblest workers, alone or in partnership; craftsmen were summoned from one town to another, and sometimes from great distances. At Delphi an order for stone which comes to about 1,100 drachmas occupies five quarrymen, one from Argos, two from Boeotia, and two from Corinth; other work is given to contractors as far as Arcadia, and they are allowed their living-expenses so long as the contract is in hand. At Epidauros the lots are less split up than anywhere else; one of them even reaches the figure of 14,000 Attic drachmas. But on this occasion the whole of Greece was making a supreme effort. A painter came from Stymphalos, the cypress-wood was supplied by a Cretan, and the heralds went cadging for tenders from Tegea to Thebes. We even know of two contractors in Argos who bid for orders first at Epidauros and then at Delphi. Argos in her turn, to build her Long Walls, sent to Athens for skilled workmen. Athens herself always gave out small orders which small contractors could undertake. The work on the Erechtheion was the occasion of a vast number of small payments. The largest sum mentioned in the Eleusis accounts of 328, amounting to 7,087 drachmas, was paid for binding the windlass with iron, i.e. for an indivisible operation; then comes an order for quarrying, transporting, and laying stone, which amounts to 2,660 drachmas; after which only one or two items rise above 500 drachmas. And foreigners followed the contract-auctions in Attica as keenly as elsewhere; out of twenty orders put up to auction at Eleusis, thirteen were secured by twelve Metics, as against seven which went to two citizens. For such competition to be allowed, desired, and actually encouraged everywhere, each city in Greece must have felt incapable of accomplishing by her own resources any project of public works which rose above the ordinary.
Puny as industry was, it could not always confine itself to executing orders. Sometimes it produced in advance. The retailers and exporters enabled the craftsmen to work regularly without troubling too much about the demand. The shoe-maker made to measure and sold ready-made. The armourer had to provide for sudden, large demands. When the Thirty confiscated the factory of Lysias and Polemarchos, they found in stock great quantities of gold, silver, and ivory, and seven hundred finished shields. In Thebes a band of insurgents broke into the armourers’ shops and fitted themselves out with lances and swords. But the craftsmen had no advantage in producing without cease and sinking capital in the shape of stock. The demand was too restricted. Even the armourer was afraid of the repercussion of political events. Demosthenes asks his guardian why his armour works have paid nothing during his minority; it is not, he says, for want of work, as is proved by the accounts of the output; then is it because the arms manufactured could not be sold? Here, certainly, we have over-production. And here we have its effects: in Aristophanes the merchants weep over the cuirasses, trumpets, crests, helmets, and javelins for which they cannot find buyers. As a rule the manufacturer made his arrangements so that production should not outstrip orders to a dangerous extent, and hired out the slaves whom he could not employ. In the IVth century he was perpetually concerned with keeping his personnel down to what was absolutely necessary. According to Xenophon, once the blacksmith or bronze-worker neglects to regulate his work by his sales, “down goes the price of his goods, and his business is ruined.” If the industry of Laureion yas the only one which absorbed labour indefinitely, it was because only the silver-market absorbed output indefinitely.
The returns of industry reached a high figure. In comparison with the natural product, the manufactured product was dear. Its price had to be in proportion to the normal interest on money and the remuneration of labour. The sums paid for the hire of slaves give valuable information on this point. Xenophon reckons that if the State buys 1,200 miners, and uses the hire paid for their labour in buying more, it will be able to raise their number to 6,000 in five or six years. If, therefore, the obol paid each day for each miner is capitalized for about five and a half years it will be possible to multiply the number of miners by five; this represents an annual profit of 33% on slaves who cost on an average 180 drachmas. For the skilful worker the hire is greater, but so is the purchasing price. Let us see what Demosthenes’ father gets from his two factories. From 20 cabinet-makers he obtains a yearly profit of 12 minas, i.e. one obol per man per day. But together they are worth at least 40 minas. Thus they bring in at most 30%). His 32 or 33 armourers bring a net yearly profit of 30 minas; according to the orator, whose interest it is to exaggerate, they are worth “up to five and six minas per head, and never less than three,” or an average of three or four minas; so the income is between 23% and 31%. Lastly, as daily hire for his shoe-makers, Timarchos takes 2 obols per man and one obol extra for the foreman; at 4 minas a man and 6 minas for the foreman, we again get 30%. In sum, below 25% the income from industry is on the low side, above 30% it is rather high. When iEschines the philosopher wanted to open a perfumery business he borrowed money from a bank at 36%; it was sheer madness. But to repay this debt he obtained funds at 18%. Then he might have made a success, if he had only had the qualifications of a manufacturer.
At 30% the income from industry was equal to two and a half times the normal interest. But it entailed a fairly big risk, the death of the slaves. A percentage must be deducted as sinking-fund. If the slave in the mine gave in appearance a rather higher return than the slave who made furniture or shoes or metal goods, it was just because his work was more unhealthy and his life more exposed. The difference in return did not therefore depend on the number of persons employed, i.e. the size of the concern. The plant was neither so complicated nor so expensive that concentration in a single concern would diminish the general costs. Small-scale industry was at least as remunerative as large- scale. Fortunes were made in the mines which were enormous for the time. By lucky digging, Callias made the 200 talents which earned him the nickname of Laccoplutos (Grubenbaron, as the Germans say); his son Hipponicos passed for the richest man in all Greece; Nicias owned 100 talents; the firm of Epicrates realized that sum in a year; when Diphilos was condemned to the confiscation of his property for illicit exploitation, 160 talents were found in his coffers. But the Athenian who invested a large capital in mining business had no other advantage over the man who risked only a few thousand drachmas than that he acquired several concessions at once. He increased his profits only in arithmetical proportion. He even added, to the expenses which would fall on several small concessionnaires, the cost of a manager, which was very heavy. This question of the return covers all the rest, in the sense that there is no industry on a large scale where the amalgamation of small concerns does not ipso facto cause a considerable saving.
But we should have a very incomplete notion of Greek industry if we neglected the moral aspect. In a people with a lively imagination and acute wits the crafts readily assumed an aesthetic character. Here there was no machine ruling over the man who minded it, and forcing him to repeat the same motion over and over again, as if he were himself an automatic driving-gear. Tasks were not necessarily monotonous; they might even develop a natural bent. There was no mass production, done in feverish haste, piled up in the darkness by nameless hands. The craftsman did his work in a little workshop under the eyes of the passer-by. He did not drudge at it from morning to night, but took his time to finish everything that passed through his hands. Even for export he was asked to supply articles of value. Eye and hand were exercised at leisure, amour-propre was aroused, and technical progress was achieved in a glad spirit. This joy in work, the collaboration of creative thought and obedient tool, the love of free play ennobling the daily endeavour, all this somehow shed a ray of light on the commonest object and made the workman an artist. Was he a sculptor or a mere decorator, the Thrasymedes of Paros who chiselled the chryselephantine statue of Asclepios at Epidauros, and then executed doors of cypress-wood plated with ivory and a coffered ceiling? What name are we to give to the marble- workers who earned a modest wage cutting fine flutings on the columns of the Erechtheion? When the Cerameicos potter made and decorated humble receptacles for oil and wine, he was a Greek working for Greeks. The air which blew about the working quarters of Athens had passed over
FIG. 42. THE VASE-PAINTER. ATTIC CUP. (D.A., Fig. 7340.)
the Parthenon, and in it the lowest workman breathed a spirit of perfect harmony. By personal endeavour new forms and motives were invented without number; even the busiest workshops did not reproduce their models twice. Plato’s contemporaries could say of industry, as of art, “Everything that we Greeks take, we transform into beauty.”
Let us visit the workers in their workshops and living- quarters; let us see at close range the small men who worked with their hands.
The skilled workers were called after their trades. The labourers, “those,” as Plato says, “who sell the service of their arms,” were called “wage-earners” (misthotoi). Under them were the assistants, servants, and apprentices. One and all were either free men, whether citizens or foreigners, or else slaves, but the lower you go in the scale of labour the more Metics and slaves do you find. To act as a labourer for a few days was generally for the citizen a temporary means of keeping himself, one of the extremities to which sudden misfortune might reduce a man.
As a rule the hiring of service was not the occasion of a forma] contract. One craftsman made an agreement with another for the execution of certain work, sometimes of a single task, and it is often difficult to say whether one of these collaborators was the subordinate or the partner of the other. Between the employer, whether he was a workshop- owner or a customer, and the employee, whether labourer or craftsman, the relationship was loose from a legal point of view, and the terms of the agreement were free. Plato, who was prepared to make regulations for everything, would have had officials to supervise the workers and to fix their wages. But the Athenian State refrained from entering on this path. The authorities never once thought of limiting the working day. Questions of payment, in case of dispute, simply went before the law-courts. A man could claim any remuneration due to him by legal proceedings, and cases between ship-owners and seamen or dock-workers were in the competence of the Nautodikai of the Peirseeus. In only one case do we find the authorities prescribing a salary; the Astynomoi did not allow women who played the flute, harp, or cithara to take more than two drachmas, and when several applicants wished to engage the same woman they assigned her by lot; but this was a police measure. Nor did the hygiene and safety of the workshop interest the city. The employment of a free child at turning a mill was prohibited on pain of death; but the very severity of the punishment proves that it was intended, not to protect the child against too heavy labour, but to preserve the son of a citizen from servitude. The mining laws treated as crimes the destruction of pit-props and the smoking of galleries, but this was in order to prevent the rapacious concessionnaire, not from killing his miners, but from destroying public property. On principle, therefore, industry enjoyed complete liberty.
Technical progress made apprenticeship necessary in almost every profession. The advantage of agriculture, to Xenophon’s mind, is that, to succeed, it is sufficient to keep your eyes open and to ask questions; the other arts require a long experience before you can live decently by them. “If you want to make a man a shoe-maker, a mason, a blacksmith… you send him to a master who can teach him.” Even the cook took lessons from a master cook. A formal contract, often in writing, fixed the amount to be paid by the apprentice’s family, the length of the indentures, and the obligations on both sides. Since the sculptors and
FIG. 43. COMPETITION OF APPRENTICE VASE-PAINTERS. HYDRIA FROM RUVO. (D.A., Fig. 3041.)
painters demanded very high premiums, poor men could only go into their studios as assistants. This was how Lysippos and Protogenes began. The learner was subjected to harsh discipline, and was not always sure of learning his trade thoroughly, for the fear of competition made the master distrustful, and he did not communicate his most precious secrets. The importance attached to professional education is attested by the apprentices’ competitions. The vase- painters represent their pupils bent over ornamental details, while Athene and Victory come and crown them. On the pedestal of a monument dedicated by a potter we read these verses: “Among those who combine earth, water, and fire in their art Bacchios won the first place by his gifts, over every rival, in the judgement of the whole of Greece, and in all the competitions organized by this city he won the crown.”
Men out of work used to look for engagements on the Agora, where a special place was set apart for them, the Colonos. So the “Colonites” were the unemployed. Engagements by the year generally ran from the 16th Anthesterion (March). There was a reason for this date in the country, where it marked the resumption of work after the winter; the agricultural workers passed it on to all classes of workers. The beginning of the new period was observed with joyous celebrations.
The worker’s day began very early. He rose before daylight. Aristophanes amuses himself with a description of
FIG. 44. BRONZE-WORKER’S STUDIO: CASTING AND PUTTING TOGETHER. ATTIC BLACK-FIGURE CUP, IN THE BERLIN MUSEUM. (Perrot, Vol. X, P. 361.)
the scene. “As soon as the cock sends forth his morning song, they all jump out of bed, blacksmiths, potters, leather- dressers, shoe-makers, bathmen, flour-dealers, lyre-turners, and shield-makers; they slip on their shoes and rush off to their work in the dark.” Work no doubt went on until sunset. In the mines, where it never ceased, there were successive ten-hour shifts. For night work the millers, bakers, and pastry-cooks paid wages at skilled rates.
Inside the workshops painted on the vases we often see clothes hanging on the wall. When a man was working he wanted to be comfortable. For sedentary work he bared his upper part and legs, or took off everything, wearing only a cap. In the forges and potteries, the more clothes there are hanging on the wall, the more vases hang there too. Going near the fire made a man thirsty.
FIG. 45. BRONZE-WORKER’S STUDIO: FINISHING. SAME CUP. (Ibid., Fig. 360.)
In the absence of machines, and with only a moderate division of labour, the craftsman and the labourer had relatively varied occupations. For tasks done by several men
FIG. 46. SHOE-MAKER AT WORK. ATTIC CUP, IN THE BRITISH MUSEUM. (D.A., Fig. 6688.)
together, and especially for hard or monotonous work, the time was set by music. The flute, the pipe, and the whistle governed motions and gave orders in the ship-building yards. There were old songs for every trade, and for each operation in it. The airs which Calypso and Circe sang as they span and wove were known by all the women. Others were sung when the corn was pounded or milled. Harvesters, millers, fishermen, rowers, bathmen, all had their chanty. With the cultivation of the vine the Greeks took to Egypt the Song of the Wine-Press. Like dancing and gymnastics, manual labour was made rhythmical and gay.
Shop and workshop were open to visitors and idlers. As in Hesiod’s time, men liked to go into the forge and to stand peacefully watching the workmen as they handled tongs, hammer, and polisher. They went to the barber’s as the Frenchman goes to his café. Young men made appointments to meet and chat at the perfumer’s. Socrates was always sure of finding an audience at the statuary’s or the armourer’s; when he wished to meet Euthydemos he went with a crowd of friends into a saddler’s shop, and it was the leather-dresser Simon who took down his sayings in a diary.
The employer did not keep a great distance between himself and his men. On feast-days they met at the sacrifice and at the sacred meal, of which he bore the cost. The epistatai of the Erechtheion offer a victim “together with the workmen.” At Eleusis the public slaves get each a good hunk of meat and about a gallon of good ordinary wine. It is a big present.
While labour does not appear too severe in the small workshops, it presents a very different spectacle in the mines. At Laureion each shift did ten hours’ work after ten hours’ rest. Five hewers, followed by twenty or twenty-five carriers, went one after the other to the face of the workings. In galleries between two and three feet wide and between two feet and a little over three feet high, they had often to crawl, and always to dig on their knees, on their stomachs, or on their backs. We can guess what the ventilation was like in these narrow passages. The heat was cruel. Heaped up bodies and smoky lamps made the air unbreathable. No hygienic precautions were taken. Nevertheless, we must not apply to Laureion the melancholy descriptions which are true of the mines of Egypt and Spain. Slaves though they were, the miners of Attica were not treated like convicts. The smaller concessionnaires mixed with the hewers, so their existence must have been endurable. Naturally the owner was prevented by his own interest from taking unnecessary risks with the health of his workers; they gave a high and steady output which he could not have got from exhausted bodies. The miners of Laureion were not shut away for the rest of their lives, like the quarrymen buried in the latomiai of Syracuse, who married there and begot children who fled screaming at the sight of a horse or an ox. At the centre of the district, at Thoricos, there was a theatre which could seat five thousand spectators; the mass of labourers were not denied all distractions. That slaves should flee to Deceleia, when Sparta called them to freedom, was only natural; but Laureion was never the scene of a general revolt, like Messenia or Sicily.
Where there were many workers, and the employer did not wish to manage his concern himself, he placed at their head a works-manager or foreman. Nicias had the work of his mines directed by a man to whom he had paid a talent. Demosthenes’ father kept in his armour factory an overseer who, after the death of the chief, had full powers of proxy. Midas managed Athenogenes’ perfumery works with all the rights which to-day are conferred by signature. The nine or ten shoe-makers of Timarchos were directed by a workshop foreman. At Eleusis seventeen public slaves, employed on the temple works, had one foreman, and twenty-eight free workers, brought from Megara, had two. The foremen were usually slaves, but sometimes freedmen or foreigners. They may have made a bit on the feeding of their men, since it was they who did the catering. They had a name for being very hard. “Slave,” says a comic poet, “beware of serving a former slave; when the bull is resting he forgets the yoke.” They had an agile arm and a ready whip. A vase painting shows us, in a pottery shop, a slave hung up by his arms and legs and lashed unmercifully. (See FIG. 26.) The iron rings found here and there in the galleries of Laureion speak volumes about the discipline which reigned in the mines. But such treatment was confined to slaves. The law of Athens protected the person of the free man against every chastisement and every constraint.
The return of labour varied according to the trade and according to the period. We can calculate the time taken by the marble-workers to flute the columns of the Erechtheion. The five men of the gang which was most employed needed about sixty days to do twenty-four flutings with flat ridges, 19 ft. 6 in. long. That makes about nineteen inches per mail per day. It is not much. Gn the other hand, at Eleusis in 329-8 the gang of three bricklayers, working steadily, laid in one day 413 squares, 17¾ in. by 17¾ in. by 4 in., i.e. altogether about 300 cubic feet. In the ancient galleries of Laureion, at points where the sterile rock is of the hardest limestone, the face of the workings, which are at least two feet high and wide, is cut in at regular intervals of four or five inches; each of these cuttings shows the normal output of five hewers working one after the other, each so long as his lamp burned, i.e. two hours. Therefore each man hewed about 250 cubic inches in an hour; this result, obtained with the pick and pitching-tool, is higher than that demanded to-day on the same sites from gun-powder and dynamite.
We now have to consider the question of wages.
Certain labourers, even in the IVth century, received no other remuneration than their food for the day. Otherwise it would not have been specified in the accounts that the workers who received wages had to feed themselves “at home.” But this mode of payment had almost disappeared in Attica, except in the country. We have seen above that even the public slaves received a ration-allowance of 180 drachmas a year in money, and drew nothing in kind but clothing, and that their foreman, who did not receive clothing, had in addition to his keep a salary of 100 drachmas.
Whereas the public slave was paid at every Prytany, ten times a year, the workman was paid by the day or by the job. In the last third of the Vth century the price at Athens of labour by the day was one drachma. No difference was made in view of either the social position or the trade of the worker, and the labourer was paid as much for his day’s work as the craftsman. But mere assistants received only 3 obols. For agricultural labourers food was reckoned at 2 ob., and they were given 4 ob. in cash. In the IVth century wages by the day tended in general to rise and to vary. In the years 395-391 a gang of bricklayers, consisting of a master mason and two lads, was paid from 4 dr. to 4 dr. 4 ob., the master getting 2 dr. and the lads 1 dr. or 1 dr. 2 ob. each. At Delphi, about the middle of the century, the plasterers received 30 Æginetan drachmas a month or 1 dr. 2½ ob. in Attic money a day. At Eleusis, in 329-8, the old wage of one drachma was only given to assistants; the labourers received 1½ dr., and the skilled workers 2 dr. (sawyers) or 2½ dr. (bricklayers, plasterers, carpenters).
But work did not go on the whole year round. There were many days when nothing was done. The Athenian calendar contained about sixty holidays, about as many as our own, including Sundays. On working days the citizen went to the law-court or the Assembly, which brought him the allowance of two or three obols. Moreover, there was not enough work to keep all hands constantly employed, and the free workman was not disposed to devote all his time to his trade. We find a gang of thirty-three men working full strength two days out of seven; on the other days two, four, twelve, fourteen, and even twenty-three are absent. When the marble-workers execute the fluting of the columns of the Erechtheion, the three gangs which contain citizens never do more than 22 or 23 drachmas worth of work per man in thirty-six or thirty-seven days, while the three gangs of slaves, directed by a slave or a Metic, do work worth 27, 35, and even 38 drachmas. The yearly salary of the architect was calculated on a basis of 2 dr. a day, at the time when the masons were earning 21/2 dr. a day; this proves with certainty that the latter were idle for at least one fifth of the year and probably much more.1
From at least the Vth century onward work was also done by the piece. In the Erechtheion accounts the sawyers are sometimes paid by the day and sometimes by the saw-cut, the carpenters receive so much for each beam shaped or each plank laid, the decorative joiners who make the panels of the ceiling fit the frames at 6 dr. apiece and fasten the mouldings at 3 dr. apiece, and the masons wall up the intervals of the columns at 10 dr. each. For the fluting of the columns 300 dr. are paid, whatever may be the strength of the gang which does the work and whatever time they take over it. Rosettes for the soffits are ordered at the fixed price of 14 dr. The marble statuettes of the frieze cost so much per subject— 60 dr. for a full-sized figure, 30 dr. for a medium figure, 20 dr. for a child. Work by the measure, a variety of work by the piece, is also done. The stone-cutters have a tariff which takes both material and size into account. Plastering and painting are done by the linear foot or by the square foot.
Payment by the piece and by the measure seems to have developed along with the division of labour, at the expense of payment by the day. In the IVth century the cutting, carriage, and transport of stones are done by the piece. At Eleusis the moulding of bricks one foot and a half square costs 36 dr. per thousand including clay, and 40 dr. without clay, the carriage of the same bricks costs, according to the distance, 15, 17, or 25 dr. per thousand, and the laying, which in 395-1 cost between 12 and 15 dr. per thousand, may reach 17 dr. in 329-8. The measurer and the carrier of the corn are entitled to 71/2 ob. and 4 ob. respectively per 100 medimni (8d. and 4d. a bushel). Inscriptions on stone are paid at various rates. In Athens the carving of decrees is priced at a tariff which rises by tens—20 dr. for 1,000 characters, 30 for 1,500, 40 for 2,000, and so on. At Epidauros the letters are reckoned at one drachma per hundred, sometimes at round rates of 10, 20, and 30 Æginetan drachmas, and sometimes exactly, fractions being taken into account. The stone-cutters at Delphi in 338 receive one Æginetan drachma for a hundred letters.
Work by the day and work by the job gradually came to be apportioned by agreement, rough work being left to plain day-labourers, and the task which required manual skill being reserved for workers who were able to put their soul into it if they took time over it. In 408 the men working on the Erechtheion were paid a drachma a day, as labourers or as craftsmen, as well as working by the job. Towards the middle of the IVth century the same kind of work was remunerated in different ways, according to the amount of finish required. At Delphi we have a good example which shows that the falling off of work by the day was in proportion to the improvement of technical processes; the same contractor does the plastering of plain stones by the day and that of worked stones at 4 dr. per face. Work by the piece does not seem to have been an economy for the customer. Here, indeed, is a case where, combined with the contract system, it costs more. Three bricklaying jobs are done at Eleusis. In two of them, which are paid by the day, the laying of a thousand bricks comes to 13 dr. 2 ob.; in the third, a contractor charges 17 dr. the thousand. He thus makes a profit of 21-22%, for which he has to engage and supervise the workmen and to be responsible for bad work. Gradually work by the job tended to drive out work by the day, even for plain tasks. It was better suited to an age in which the works contract placed a professional craftsman between the workman and the customer, and the distinction between the skilled worker and the plain labourer was accentuated.’
But when we speak of wages we must determine their real value. What standard of living could the craftsman and the labourer attain? That there was suffering in the IVth century there is no doubt. We have only to listen to the wail of the fuller in the comedy. “In our trade we have the earnest of a livelihood, and we die of hunger all the year round, for ever hoping.” But perhaps unemployment was more frequent in a trade in which competition was keener than in others. Let us look at the question as a whole. First of all, we must remember the abstemiousness of the South. In old days, says Aristophanes, if you went out for the day, “you took a calabash of drink and some dry bread, a couple of onions, and three olives.” Clothes were very simple, and were made for a great part at home. For dwelling there were a few small rooms in a house of sun-baked brick. Let us try to calculate the cost of living in these circumstances.
Food consisted of two elements: (i) the sitos, i.e. cereals in the form of bread, scone, or porridge; (ii) the opsonion, i.e. fresh or dried vegetables, meat, which was almost always pig, fresh or salt fish, and lastly fruit, chiefly olives and figs. The usual drink was wine, very much diluted, or spring water. It is easy to calculate the cost of the sitos. The grown man’s ration was reckoned at one choenix of wheat (nearly two pints) or two choeniees of barley meal a day. This was the big ration, which was demanded by the Spartan soldier in the field; he regarded it as very large, since he considered that half as much was enough for his servant.
At the end of the Vth century, therefore, when wheat was at 3 dr. the medimnus, the worker’s sitos cost him 22J dr. a year for 7f medimni. With 60 dr. a year, or one obol a day, he was well fed. With an additional 60 dr. he could meet his other expenses. A single man lived comfortably on 120 dr. in the time of Pericles. It was enough if he worked one day in three. Now let us suppose the typical case of the man with a wife and two children to keep. Allow three full rations for the four of them, and their food will cost 180 dr. Clothing may be reckoned at 50 dr., housing at 36 dr., and sundry expenses at 14 dr. This makes 280 dr. altogether. These figures agree quite well with the salary of the architect, who must have been able to maintain a family decently on his 360 dr. The workman who earned one drachma a day could feed his family, if it was not too large, without even being compelled to work on every working day.
In the IVth century, when the general rise in prices brought the cost of corn up to 5 dr. the medimnus, the single man’s food came to 100 dr., and that of a family of four to 300 dr. But the other expenses had not increased at the same rate, since the public slave lived well on 180 dr. a year plus clothing. A worker could, therefore, keep a wife and two children on 450 dr. It is true that the architect now received 750 dr., and a middle-class townsman complained that he could only just live on 540 dr.; but in these times the upper classes were beginning to have expensive wants which were not felt to the same degree by the working classes. Therefore a plain assistant, getting one drachma a day, could, if he worked three hundred days in the year, ensure a good average standard of living for his wife; but he was obliged to practise moderation and to be content with reduced rations if he had children. The labourer who earned 11/2 dr. could feed two children, provided he worked on all days but holidays. The skilled worker with 2 dr. or 21/2 dr. could save 150 or 300 dr, if he was constantly employed, or else he could rest three days in eight, or even one in two. While the unskilled worker, burdened with a family, could only manage by dint of hard work and privations, the skilled worker or small craftsman could bring up several children and give them, according to the work he did, an average or high standard of living.
1 The advantage of the architect and the officials over the craftsmen and labourers lies just in the fact that they escape unemployment. Their emoluments are not at a higher rate, but they are fixed by the year and paid in halves, tenths, or twelfths. In the Vth century the Athenian architect gets 360 dr., one per day. In the first half of the following century the architect at Epidauros gets more, thanks to the ^Eginetan drachma. In the second half, the architect at Eleusis receives 720 dr. (2 dr. per day). At Delphi the architect is paid 360 Æginetan drachmas for at least eight years, then, in 345, he gets double, and in 342 four times the amount (almost three times as much as his colleague at Eleusis). Salaries come more and more to depend on talent and reputation.