The real interest rate may be the most important price in the economy because it represents the opportunity cost of spending. The opportunity cost principle tells you that before spending money, you should ask, “Or what?” You can spend money now, or you can save it, earn interest, and buy even more in the future. The real interest rate, denoted by r, tells you how large this opportunity cost is—how much more stuff you’ll be able to buy if you wait until next year. So, the real interest rate—which is the nominal interest rate adjusted for inflation—is the price that determines this year’s aggregate expenditure.
The real interest rate is also critical because it’s one of the levers policy makers use to influence the economy. The Federal Reserve raises the interest rate—which increases the opportunity cost of spending—when it wants to induce people to spend less. And when the Fed wants to stimulate more spending, it reduces the interest rate, which reduces the opportunity cost of spending money today. As such, careful adjustments to the real interest rate can help offset booms and busts.
These insights inform the roadmap ahead. Our goal is to develop a comprehensive framework for understanding how interest rates affect the economy and why rates rise and fall. We’re going to proceed in two steps. First, we’ll figure out how the real interest rate affects GDP—a relationship that we’ll call the IS curve. Second, we’ll assess how changing financial conditions determine the real interest rate, summarizing our findings in a line we’ll call the MP curve. Putting them together will yield a framework you can use to analyze changes in economic conditions. And if you’re puzzled about how these two curves got their names, don’t worry, we’ll also get to that.
Before we can get there, we need to lay the foundation, analyzing how the real interest rate affects aggregate expenditure. We’ll do this by separately exploring how the real interest rate shapes each of the components of aggregate expenditure: consumption, planned investment, government purchases, and finally, net exports. (We explored some of these themes in greater detail in Chapters 25–28 so we’ll just hit the key ideas here.)
The real interest rate is central to your spending decisions as a consumer because of the opportunity cost principle: You can save and earn interest on any income you don’t spend. As a result, the real interest rate represents the opportunity cost of boosting this year’s consumption spending. The lower the real interest rate is, the lower this opportunity cost. That’s why a low real interest rate leads to more consumption.
The real interest rate is also the cost of borrowing. If you need a loan in order to buy a car, a house, or some other big-ticket item, your bank will charge you interest. The lower the real interest rate is, the less you’ll have to repay your bank, which is another reason that low interest rates lead people to increase their spending on big-ticket items.
Note, however, that there’s one group for whom a low real interest rate will reduce consumption, and that’s people who rely on interest payments for their income. In their case, lower interest rates translate into less income, which can lead them to cut back on their consumption spending. While this describes some people (particularly retirees), across the whole economy this effect is relatively small. And so, on average, lower interest rates lead to more consumption.
For businesses considering capital investments, the real interest rate is important, again because of the opportunity cost principle: If you spend your money buying new equipment or structures, you can’t put that money in the bank to earn interest. And so the opportunity cost of investing in new capital is lower when real interest rates are lower. As a result, low real interest rates lead to more investment spending. Indeed, a low enough interest rate can be the difference that makes billions of dollars of investment projects worth pursuing, which is why investment is particularly sensitive to the real interest rate.
Low interest rates reduce the cost of interest payments on government debt. These interest payments—which are a transfer from the government to those it borrows from—don’t directly affect aggregate expenditure. But low interest payments mean that there’s more money left in the government budget for spending on roads, bridges, and other forms of aggregate expenditure. As a result, lower interest rates can lead to an increase in government purchases, particularly for state governments, which are often required by law to balance their budgets. Low interest rates don’t always spur more government purchases though, because governments might use their extra funds to pay down their debt instead.
Net exports also depend on the real interest rate, but through an indirect mechanism: Low interest rates make the U.S. dollar cheaper, and this increases net exports (which is exports less imports). Let’s take each of these steps in turn.
A low real interest rate in the United States leads international money managers to send their funds to other countries that offer better returns. This means they’ll demand fewer U.S. dollars, leading the dollar to become cheaper. So the initial effect of a lower interest rate is that it takes fewer yen, euros, or yuan (the currencies of Japan, Europe, and China) to buy an American dollar.
This cheaper dollar increases exports and reduces imports. Start by considering exports: An American-made car that costs US$10,000 (“US$” means “in U.S. dollars”) now sells for fewer yen, euros, or yuan than it did before. This effective price cut leads foreigners to buy more of our exports. As a result, spending on our exports rises. Next, consider imports: A cheaper dollar means that it now takes more U.S. dollars to buy a €10,000 car (the € sign means “euros”). This effective price rise leads Americans to buy fewer imports. If the quantity of imports declines by enough to offset the higher prices, then total spending by Americans on imported goods will also fall. Put these effects together, and lower real interest rates lead to a cheaper U.S. dollar, causing exports to rise and imports to fall, and hence higher net exports.
Let’s summarize what we’ve found so far. We discovered that a decrease in the real interest rate leads to an increase in every component of aggregate expenditure, boosting consumption, investment, possibly government purchases, and net exports.
Of these effects, the boost to investment is usually the most important because investment—both in machinery and housing—is particularly sensitive to the interest rate.
The top row of Figure 3 shows that consumption, investment, government purchases, and net exports are each higher when the real interest rate is lower. The bottom row simply adds these up to illustrate that aggregate expenditure—which is the sum of each of these forms of spending—is higher when the real interest rate is lower.
This insight—that a lower real interest rate will boost aggregate expenditure—is central to the framework we’re developing. We summarize this finding as:
Recall our previous finding that businesses adjust their output to meet demand, so that output adjusts until it’s equal to aggregate expenditure. As a result, a lower real interest rate which boosts aggregate expenditure will increase the level of GDP:
Finally, potential output is determined by long-run factors that are unaffected by these business cycle changes. Since potential output is unchanged, the interest-rate-induced increase in output also increases output relative to potential output, leading to a more positive output gap.
That’s it! We’ve uncovered the link by which lower real interest rates lead to higher real GDP and a more positive output gap.
Figure 4 shows this relationship by graphing the IS curve, which illustrates how lower real interest rates lead to more spending and hence more output and a more positive output gap. It’s called the IS curve because it describes Investment and Spending decisions. And it illustrates the Interest Sensitivity of output. (Historically, it was called the IS curve because Investment is the key form of interest-sensitive spending, and Saving is used to fund investment.)
You construct the economy’s IS curve by adding up the level of aggregate expenditure at each real interest rate. Because output adjusts to the level of aggregate expenditure, this also reveals the level of GDP, and then it’s just a matter of comparing GDP to potential GDP to calculate the corresponding output gap. Calculate this output gap when the real interest rate is 1%, 2%, 3%, and so on, then connect these dots, and you’ve estimated the IS curve.
You are probably used to thinking about a demand curve as showing this year’s demand for a specific product, like gas. In many ways, the IS curve is similar—it shows this year’s demand for all types of output and so you can think of it as showing the macroeconomic demand for output.
As with a demand curve, the vertical axis shows a price—in this case, that price is the real interest rate, which is the opportunity cost of spending money this year rather than next. And the horizontal axis shows the corresponding quantity—the output gap—which is the total quantity of goods and services purchased across the whole economy, relative to potential output.
That’s because a lower real interest rate decreases the opportunity cost of making purchases this year, leading people across the whole economy to respond by buying more goods and services. Or you can say this the other way: The higher the real interest rate is, the greater the opportunity cost of buying stuff this year (rather than next), and so the smaller the quantity of stuff people demand this year. And while we call the IS curve a curve, as Figure 4 illustrates, it could also be a straight line.
The IS curve is a valuable tool for forecasting economic conditions. For instance, can you forecast what the output gap will be if the real interest is 4%?
Figure 5 illustrates how to figure this out. First, locate the 4% real interest rate on the vertical axis. Then look across until you find the IS curve. Now look down to discover that the corresponding level of GDP is 5% below its potential level. That’s it, you’ve now got your forecast.
Of course, this is your forecast, holding other things constant. If other factors change, then so should your forecast. This points to another way the IS curve can be helpful: You can use it to forecast the consequences of changing economic conditions.
In Figure 5, you started by looking at point A, where the real interest rate is 4%. Now consider what happens if policy makers cut the real interest rate to 1%. Locate the new 1% real interest rate on the vertical axis and look across until you hit the IS curve. Look down, and you’ll see that it corresponds to an output gap of
Notice that this change in the real interest rate led the economy to move from one point on the IS curve to another point on the same curve. This makes sense: The point of the IS curve is to illustrate how the output gap responds to changes in the real interest rate, and so changes in the real interest rate lead to a movement along the IS curve.
This is where it’s important that you distinguish between:
Later in the chapter, we’ll look at the changes in other factors that can shift the IS curve.
What caused the early 1980s recession?
In 1979, newly appointed Federal Reserve Chair Paul Volcker pledged to eliminate the double-digit inflation that was then plaguing the U.S. economy. He figured that if he engineered an economic slowdown, inflation would fall, as businesses rarely raise their prices when the economy is weak.
To create this slowdown, the Federal Reserve jacked up the interest rate. At its peak, the nominal interest rate was 20%, and the real interest rate was as high as 10%. Just as our analysis suggests, a high real interest rate led businesses to sharply curtail investment spending, households to cut back on consumption, and it caused the U.S. dollar to rise, leading net exports to fall. Aggregate expenditure fell, causing GDP to decline.
The recession deepened, and protests mounted. Indebted farmers blockaded the Federal Reserve building with their tractors; construction workers mailed their complaints on pieces of lumber, and car dealers sent the Fed coffins containing the keys of unsold cars. A Texas congressman threatened to impeach Volcker.
High real interest rates ended up being too successful at slowing the economy. GDP fell to be far below potential output, which created a very negative output gap. The unemployment rate rose from under 6% in 1979 to a peak of nearly 11% in 1982. This episode settled any remaining debate about the importance of the real interest rate in shaping the business cycle. It vividly demonstrated the relevance of the IS curve, as this bout of high interest rates led to lower levels of aggregate expenditure, lower GDP, and a sharply negative output gap.
At this point, you’ve got a good handle on the IS curve: It tells you what the output gap will be at each real interest rate. But what determines the real interest rate, and what could cause it to change? Figuring that out is our next task.